« August 2009 |
Main
| October 2009 »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 30, 2009 at 11:42 PM
Permalink
Comments (11)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 30, 2009 at 11:04 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (27)
Brad DeLong places government policy into "three boxes," fiscal policy, monetary policy, and capital markets policy:
Monetary Policy, Fiscal Policy, Capital Markets Policy, by Brad DeLong: Paul
Krugman is three doors down the hall right now, but I am going to talk to him
through the magic of the internet rather than mosying down:
Does unconventional monetary policy solve the zero bound problem?: Some
comments on my post on the true cost of fiscal stimulus argue that the zero
lower bound aka liquidity trap isn’t really binding, because the Fed is using
other measures to expand the economy. A few commenters imply that I haven’t been
paying attention.
Well, yes I’m aware that BB is doing a bunch of unconventional stuff. But the
available — albeit thin — evidence is that it takes a huge expansion of the
Fed’s balance sheet to accomplish as much as would be achieved by a quite modest
cut in the Fed funds rate. And the Fed isn’t willing to expand its balance sheet
to the $10 trillion or so it would take to be as expansionary as it “should” be
given, say, a Taylor rule.
Which means that the zero bound is still binding, which means that right now
we’re very much still in liquidity trap territory.
I would put it somewhat differently. There's fiscal policy--using the government
to expand output holding the risky long-term real interest rate that governs
business investment and household borrowing decisions constant. There's monetary
policy---using open-market operations to boost or retard the economy holding the
short-term safe nominal interest rate constant. And then there is capital
markets policy: operating on the wedge between the risky long-term real interest
rate and the short-term safe nominal interest rate.
If you set up those three boxes, then a huge number of things fall under the
rubric of "capital markets policy"--banking recapitalization. loan guarantees,
nationalizations, bank rescues, asset purchases, and the sending of signals that
alter the expected rate of future inflation.
You can call Federal Reserve policies aimed at the sending of signals that alter
the expected rate of future inflation "monetary policy" if you want, but then
you lose analytical clarity--because the way such policies work (if they work)
is not the "normal" way that "normal" monetary policy works. Normal monetary
policy works by shifting the private sector's asset holdings toward assets that
people spend more readily and rapidly, thus boosting spending. Quantitative
easing at the zero bound does not do that: it simply exchanges one zero-yield
government asset for another. What is does do is to change bond prices, rather
by raising the safe short-term nominal interest rate and thus giving people an
incentive to spend the money they already have more quickly.
I would add risk management to the definitions (e.g., I have called the
central bank the "risk absorber of last resort"). When the Fed (or any other
government agency) trades T-Bills for risky private sector assets, it changes
the overall level of risk in the private sector since the risk has been absorbed onto the Fed's balance sheet (this is not the only way to reduce risk, e.g.
government provided insurance against losses would also have this effect, and
most of these actions can also create moral hazard). The risk management function of policy is something Brad has
talked about in the past as well, and I'm not sure if he'd identify risk
management as a separate category, or whether it fits into the the
capital markets policy categories he identifies (it would also operate on the wedge between safe and risky assets by reducing the risk premium, so I'd include it there). Either way, I think it's worth
mentioning since these actions can also affect the level of economic activity. When markets are frozen with fear, reducing the chance that hidden losses will be discovered after a transaction is complete can help to restore these markets.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 30, 2009 at 12:01 PM
Permalink
Comments (31)
Bankers are, apparently, being rewarded generously for their fine performance in recent years:
HTML clipboard
In 2008, salaries of the top 10 banks reached $75 billion (up from $31
billion in 1999), while cash dividends to shareholders were only $17.5 billion.
Management took 4.3 times more than shareholders at a time when shareholders
were injecting capital and government was guaranteeing deposits.
If people were really compensated according to the value they create, wouldn't bank managers would owe us money?
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 30, 2009 at 10:20 AM in Economics, Financial System |
Permalink
Comments (18)
Andrew Leonard's bad day:
The brighter side of high unemployment, Andrew Leonard: ...BusinessWeek
contributor Gene Marks ...
gloats about how high unemployment is good for his business. I guess any
publicity is good publicity... But he didn't pick a good day. Having already
been irritated enough by David Brooks, I can't say I was exactly in the mood for
an explanation of why high unemployment is great for small businesses because
now there are so many "good, bright, educated people" who are "willing -- no,
let's admit -- grateful to work for less money and longer hours."
Even better, the bad economy provides cover for getting rid of that "dead
weight" that you were feeling too guilty to throw overboard. ... And the capper:
Because let's face it: The upside to the high unemployment rate is that it has
helped us control our payroll costs. No one's asking for raises. No one's
demanding more benefits. ...It's now easier and more politically correct to hire
part-timers, subcontractors, and other outsourced help to fill the gaps. That's
because when people are out of work, they'll do whatever they've got to do to
bring in cash.
I understand that Gene Marks is ... a small business owner (he sells customer
relationship management tools), who is attempting to speak to other small
business owners, all of whom, presumably, are also delighted that the potential
hiring pool is so chock full of talent desperate to be exploited right now.
But one wonders who exactly is supposed to purchase all those products and
services from the small businesses of the world, if unemployment creeps up to
the 10 percent mark or higher? High unemployment means low consumer demand.
Which usually means small businesses end up going out of business, or at the
very least, laying off more employees, who push the unemployment rate even
higher. And so on. Low employment might mean it would be harder to find
qualified employees, but it also means more customers with money burning a hole
in their pockets. Which scenario, do you think, is better for society in
general?
I have no problem with contrarian arguments. But a look back at
the oeuvre of Gene Marks suggests that in his efforts to be routinely
contrarian, he ends up coming off as, well, how can I be polite? What's the
opposite of insightful?
Here's what set him off:
The decline and fall of David Brooks, by Andrew Leonard: America needs "a
moral revival," declares
David Brooks... We are drowning in a sea of debt,
and this is because we have lost our moorings; we have abandoned our tradition
of Calvinist restraint, self-denial and frugal responsibility. If we don't start
living right, we run the risk of cultural failure, that time-honored historical
pattern in which "affluence and luxury lead to decadence, corruption and
decline."
My my my. I've seen some high horses in my day, but David Brooks is perched on a
saddle so far aloft in the clouds of self-delusion that he can't even see the
earth, much less reality. Let's examine his thesis more closely.
Americans ran up a lot of debt in the last few decades. There's no question
about that. But one of the most striking developments of the last year has been
how Americans have responded to the financial crisis at an individual level. We
made a collective decision to start saving and stop spending. Is this because we
woke up one morning last fall and suddenly became born-again Calvinists? No, it
seems clear that we were responding rationally to economic incentives. The
economy crashed, unemployment surged, home prices plummeted, and presto: We all
started pinching pennies. Morality, insofar as expressed via our spending
habits, is merely a reflection of the economy.
To his credit, Brooks acknowledges this point. But then he immediately dismisses
it:
Over the past few months, those debt levels have begun to come down. But that
doesn't mean we've re-established standards of personal restraint. We've simply
shifted from private debt to public debt.
This, Brooks suggests, proves that "there clearly has been an erosion in the
country's financial values." Elsewhere he suggests that our cultural decline
began sometime around 1980.
Brooks displays a bizarre historical amnesia throughout his column. For example,
he never even mentions the transition from the Roaring Twenties to the Great
Depression. Maybe it's because the shift from decadence to thrift at that point
was also obviously a response to economic incentives. Even worse, a moral
revival didn't restore economic growth after the Crash -- government action and
ultimately the fiscal stimulus provided by World War II did the trick.
But a far more pertinent point of reference comes much earlier. Has Brooks
somehow forgotten that just nine years ago the U.S. operated under a balanced
budget and enjoyed a budget surplus? The explosion of public debt since that
point has very little to do with the moral failings of Americans, and everything
to do with objective fact. George W. Bush cut taxes, but did not match those
cuts with spending cuts. Instead, he ramped up spending dramatically, on two
wars, healthcare, and finally, a huge bailout of Wall Street.
Bruce Bartlett has calculated that even without Obama stimulus-related spending
increases, the current deficit for fiscal year 2009 would be about $1.3 trillion
instead of $1.6 trillion. If you are a believer in Keynesian economics, you can
make a pretty good case that Obama's additional spending is designed to get the
economy growing again, so as to avoid even worse deficits in the future.
Do nothing, and a shrinking economy means lower tax revenues and higher social
spending. Morality has very little to do it -- the appropriate, responsible
fiscal choice at this point is for government to spend, while the people save.
Obama would be in much better position to do what's appropriate, of course, if
he hadn't been saddled with a trillion-dollar deficit when he walked in the
door. But the responsibility for that does not belong with some widespread
betrayal of America's founding puritan values. It belongs explicitly to the
party in control over the last eight years.
Update: Paul Krugman:
Moral decay? Or deregulation?, by Paul Krugman:
Andrew Leonard is unhappy with my colleague David Brooks for suggesting that
rising debt in America reflects moral decay. Surprisingly, however, Leonard
doesn’t make what I thought was the most compelling critique.
David points out, correctly, that something changed around 1980 — that
consumers started spending a larger share of national income and that debt began
increasing. Although he doesn’t point this out, this was also when the federal
government first began running substantial deficits even in good years.
David would have you believe that what happened then was a decline in
Calvinist virtue. But, um, didn’t something else happen around 1980? Can’t quite
remember .. someone whose name begins with the letter “R”?
Yes,
Reagan did it.
The turn to budget deficits was a direct result of the new,
Irving-Kristol inspired political strategy of pushing tax cuts without
worrying about the “accounting deficiencies of government.”
Meanwhile, the surge in household debt can largely be
attributed
to financial deregulation.
So what happened? Did we lose our economic morality? No, we were the victims
of politics.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 30, 2009 at 01:09 AM in Economics, Saving, Unemployment |
Permalink
Comments (71)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 11:06 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (26)
Bruce Judson is worried about what the latest reports on economic inequality say
about our future:
New Income Inequality Data: Surprising and Frightening, by Bruce Judson: The
newest economic inequality numbers ... are frightening. Yesterday, the
Associated Press released an article titled,
US income gap widens as poor take hit in recession. The opening
paragraph of the article, based on recent census data, reads:
The recession has hit middle-income and poor families hardest, widening the
economic gap between the richest and poorest Americans as rippling job layoffs
ravaged household budgets.
The article ... failed to mention that the Census Bureau considered the
differences between 2007 and 2008, with regard to economic inequality,
statistically insignificant. But, whether the Census Data shows a
meaningful increase, or not is irrelevant. The Census Data reports that,
contrary to the
almost universal expectations of economists, economic inequality most likely
did not decrease in 2008. Experts had anticipated that the declines in income of
the rich would lead to a reversal in this groups ever–widening share of our
national income. Instead, the Census reported that the 2008 income losses by the
top 10% of Americans were offset by larger losses among middle class and
poorer Americans. ...
Early next week, my new book
It Could Happen Here will be released... The book is an
in-depth look , based on a historical analysis, of the implications of our
historically high levels of economic inequality for the nation’s ultimate,
long-term political stability. As economic inequality grows, nations
invariably become increasingly politically unstable: Should we
complacently believe that America will be different?
A central conclusion of the book is that once economic inequality reaches a
self-reinforcing cycle it is halted only by inevitably controversial,
hard-fought, bitterly opposed government action. ...
In 1928, economic inequality was near today’s levels. Franklin Roosevelt
succeeded in reversing the trend toward the continuing concentration of wealth,
but it was a turbulent battle. ...
In FDR’s era and in our own, money brings power: both explicitly and implicitly,
in hundreds of different ways, both large and small. Today, the
wealthiest Americans, together with a number of financial and corporate
interests that act on their behalf, protect their ever-increasing
influence through activities that include, among others, lobbying, supplying
expertise to the councils of government, casual conversation at dinner parties,
the potential for jobs after government service, the power to run media
advertisements that influence public opinion. Indeed, MIT economist Simon
Johnston, writing in The Atlantic asserted that the U.S. is now run by
an oligarchy...
The new inequality data suggests that the potential problems for the nation
associated with the concentration of wealth and power are even more severe than
previously recognized. Two weeks ago, I wrote that “Once income concentration
becomes a reinforcing cycle of the kind we are witnessing, it is never stopped
by pure market forces.” This mechanism is now in full swing. ...
The great strength of American democracy has always been its capacity for
self-correction. However, Robert Dahl, the eminent political scientist,
recognized that political power fueled by wealth may ultimately neutralize this
central aspect of our democracy. In his 2006 book, On Political
Equality, Dahl wrote:
As numerous studies have shown, inequalities in income and wealth are likely to
produce other inequalities..
The unequal accumulation of political resources points to an ominous
possibility: political inequalities may be ratcheted up, so to speak, to a level
from which they cannot be ratcheted down. The cumulative advantages in
power, influence, and authority of the more privileged strata may become so
great that even if less privileged Americans compose a majority of citizens they
are simply unable, and perhaps even unwilling, to make the effort it would
require to overcome the forces of inequality arrayed against them.
In the chapter following this quote, Dahl notes “that we should not assume this
future is inevitable.” He’s right. But he was clearly concerned. ...
Many current Executive Branch initiatives deserve our support and praise:
However, nothing proposed to date will effectively halt growing economic
inequality, and its corrosive impact on our economy and the long-term future of
the nation. ...
My analysis in It Could Happen
Here concludes that without a vibrant middle class, the the American
democracy as we know it, is not sustainable. Before the Great Recession,
the middle class was in
far worse shape than was
generally
acknowledged. In an economy with a
record number of job seekers for every available job, the potential for
nearly
one-half of all home mortgages to be underwater, and
increasing foreclosures, the collapse of the middle class will accelerate.
With each job loss and each foreclosure, another family becomes a member of the
former middle class.
America has never been a society sharply divided between have’s and have not’s.
Unfortunately, this new data says to me we continue to head in that
direction. Economists assumed that the Great Recession would be a circuit
breaker that would halt this advance, at least temporarily. It did not.
...
Could our democracy survive a transformation into a nation composed
principally of a privileged upper class and an underclass that struggles from
paycheck to paycheck that lacks basic economic security. My analysis of a broad
sweep of history, suggests it could not.
We will only stop the growth of economic inequality if the President and the
Congress are ready to fight in the style of Franklin Roosevelt. FDR was a
divider not a conciliator. Before World War II, he fought an all-out
war at home. Today, “There’s class warfare, all right,” as
Warren Buffett said, “but it’s my class, the rich class, that’s making war,
and we’re winning.”
I fervently hoped that we have not passed the point of no return,
described by Professor Dahl. The recent news shows we are one step further
on this road. If we continue down it, our nation may be on the path
to becoming a House divided against itself, which ultimately cannot stand.
Are you as concerned as he is? I don't know if we are headed down the path of no return or not, but the part that concerns me is that recent changes in inequality do not seem to be driven by market forces that properly evaluate and reward productive activity.
Republicans worry a lot about the effect that small changes in tax rates would have on economic activity (something there's not a lot of evidence to support) because taxes distort the relationship between effort and reward. But if the rewards have become generally separated from productive effort, particularly the large rewards at the very top of the income distribution where the Republicans argue these incentive effects are the strongest, then there are large distortions in the system that have nothing to do with taxes. That is what Republicans ought to be worried about if they are truly concerned with ensuring that the rewards people receive match their productive effort.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 06:52 PM in Economics, Income Distribution |
Permalink
Comments (38)
Andrew Leigh says this is a "a
terrific piece on social mobility":
American dreams,
by Peter Browne: When Barack Obama spoke to schoolchildren at Wakefield High
School in Virginia last week, he drew on his own experiences to argue that all
young Americans, regardless of their family’s wealth and income – even kids who
“goofed off” at high school, like he did – have the potential to rise to the
top. ...
But how typical is [this]? ... The seductive idea that anyone can move up the
income scale might mean that Americans are more tolerant of a degree of
inequality that would cause much deeper unease in many other western countries.
...
[R]ecent research drawing on a series of studies from Europe, the United States
and Australia ... has concluded ... that among comparable countries, the United
States has an unusually rigid social system and limited possibilities for
mobility. ...
President Obama is no doubt aware of this research, and has made oblique
references to the problems facing low-income families and neighborhoods in
speeches and interviews. But the mobility myth is so widely believed and so
deep-seated that it’s not surprising he hasn’t tried to confront the problem
head on. When the Economic Mobility Project [2] surveyed 2100 adults and ran ten
focus groups earlier this year it found that respondents overwhelmingly believe
that personal attributes – “like hard work and drive” – are the prime
determinants of how economically successful an individual can be. A smaller
majority also disagreed with the statement that “In the United States, a child’s
chances of achieving financial success is tied to the income of his or her
parent.”
As the studies show, that statement is true for ... a higher proportion of American children than in most comparable
countries. Among the twelve countries analyzed by economist Anna Cristina
d’Addio in a 2007 OECD report,... the United States was in a group of four –
with France, Italy and Britain – where family background plays the greatest role
in influencing adult income. Children born into a poor family in any of these
countries had a much lower chance of breaking into a higher income group than in
any of the other countries in the study. ...
Britain came out worst, with around 50 per cent of a person’s income explained
by his or her parents’ income. ... Italy and the United States weren’t far
behind, at around 47 per cent. At the other end of the range were Denmark,
Norway, Finland and Canada, where parental income explained less than 20 per
cent of the child’s eventual earnings. ...[I]t’s those four countries, rather
than the United States, that come closest to realizing the American Dream.
Some studies have found that mobility is not only limited in the United States
but has worsened in recent decades. ...
Why do some countries fare so badly...? The OECD report offers the most
comprehensive list of likely factors, but its conclusions are tentative. ... But
looking at the factors that the OECD believes contribute “significantly” to
differences in mobility, it isn’t hard to see why the United States performs
badly...
First, there’s the problem of entrenched income inequality. “In general,” says
d’Addio..., “the countries with the most equal distributions of income at a
given point in time exhibit the highest mobility across generations.” Among the
twelve countries examined in the report, the United States has the most unequal
distribution of income. ...
Equally interesting is the role of immigration in pushing up mobility. Overall,
immigrants tend to be more upwardly mobile than the broader population. ... Yet
the United States doesn’t seem to have gained the ... benefits from migration...
This clearly has something to do with how well migrant students perform at
school. ...
The other key factor identified indirectly by the OECD, and more explicitly in a
new Economic Mobility Project [8] report, is a strikingly low level of mobility
among black Americans. ... The author of the Project’s report, New York
University sociologist Patrick Sharkey, finds that growing up in a high-poverty
neighborhood “increases the risk of experiencing downward mobility and explains
a sizable portion of the black-white downward mobility gap.”
These neighborhoods usually suffer from other warning signs for low mobility
identified in the OECD report, including a high rate of male unemployment at the
time of a child’s birth and a high rate of relationship breakdown. ...
For Barack Obama, the ... reform that’s causing him the most difficulty at the
moment – healthcare – also has implications for economic mobility. Child
birth-weight is a “significant” factor in explaining low mobility, and the
child’s mental health and parents’ physical health are “significant and large”
factors, according to the OECD. Like any measures designed to break down the
rigidity that keeps many Americans poor, improvements in health will take some
time to influence overall mobility. But a system of health insurance for all
Americans would certainly have an impact in the long term.
Ironically, the remarkable rise of Barack Obama could make it harder for
Americans to recognize the shaky foundations of the American Dream. And the fact
that so many people continue to believe the myth could make the problem worse.
As the American researcher Isabel Sawhill writes, “When those who are relatively
poor believe that they or their children will rise in status over time, they are
less likely to complain about the status quo and more likely to accept the
prevailing system.” ...
Is it true that we tolerate inequality because we believe we are highly mobile, and that merit rather than family background is the most important factor in determining social outcomes? Even if it were true that merit is the most determinant of social mobility, that is not enough. The opportunity must be present before those with merit can take advantage of it, and ensuring that everyone has a chance to succeed is an important step in fixing the mobility problem. Nothing will ever be completely equal, some people will always have more opportunity than others to get ahead, but we could do a whole lot better than we are doing now at creating the opportunity for people to reach their full potential.
I am not generally predisposed to redistributive policies, and the best solution to the mobility problem is to ensure everyone has an equal chance to succeed. But since equal opportunity is a long way from reality, I believe that redistribution that compensates for differences in opportunity is justified.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 04:35 PM in Economics, Income Distribution |
Permalink
Comments (49)
I am not as negative toward naked short-selling as Matt Taibbi (feel free to convince me I'm wrong), but his
insights into the lobbying effort against financial reform are useful, and I share his concerns about the distortions (e.g. regulatory capture) this brings to the reform process:
An Inside Look at How Goldman Sachs Lobbies the Senate, by Matt Taibbi:
...Later on this week I have a story coming out in Rolling Stone
that looks at the history of the Bear Stearns and Lehman Brothers collapses.
The story ends up being more about naked short-selling and the role it
played in those incidents than I had originally planned..., but it turns out
that there’s no way to talk about Bear and Lehman without going into the
weeds of naked short-selling...
It’s the conspicuousness ... that is the issue here, and the degree to which
the SEC and the other financial regulators have proven themselves completely
incapable of addressing the issue seriously, constantly giving in to the
demands of the major banks to pare back (or shelf altogether) planned
regulatory actions. There probably isn’t a better example of “regulatory
capture” ... than this issue.
In that vein, starting tomorrow, the SEC is holding a public “round table”
on the naked short-selling issue. What’s interesting about this round table
is that virtually none of the invited speakers represent shareholders or
companies that might be targets of naked short-selling, or indeed any
activists of any kind in favor of tougher rules against the practice.
Instead, all of the invitees are either banks, financial firms, or companies
that sell stuff to the first two groups.
In particular, there are very few panelists — in fact only one, from what I
understand — who are in favor of a simple reform called “pre-borrowing.”
Pre-borrowing is what it sounds like; it forces short-sellers to actually
possess shares before they sell them.
It’s been proven to work, as last summer the SEC, concerned about predatory
naked short-selling of big companies in the wake of the Bear Stearns
wipeout, instituted a temporary pre-borrow requirement...
The lack of pre-borrow voices invited to this panel is analogous to the Max
Baucus health care round table last spring, when no single-payer advocates
were invited. So who will get to speak? Two guys from Goldman Sachs, plus
reps from Citigroup, Citadel (a hedge fund that has done the occasional
short sale, to put it gently), Credit Suisse, NYSE Euronext, and so on.
In advance of this panel and in advance of proposed changes to the financial
regulatory system, these players have been stepping up their lobbying
efforts... Goldman Sachs in particular has been making its presence felt.
Last Friday I got a call from a Senate staffer who said that Goldman had
just been in his boss’s office, lobbying against restrictions on naked
short-selling. The aide said Goldman had passed out a fact sheet about the
issue that was so ridiculous that one of the other staffers immediately
thought to send it to me. When I went to actually get the document, though,
the aide had had a change of heart.
Which was weird, and I thought the matter had ended there. But the exact
same situation then repeated itself with another congressional
staffer, who then actually passed me Goldman’s fact sheet.
Now, the mere fact that two different congressional aides were so disgusted
by Goldman’s performance that they both called me on the same day — and I
don’t have a relationship with either of these people — tells you how
nauseated they were.
I would later hear that Senate aides between themselves had discussed
Goldman’s lobbying efforts and concluded that it was one of the most
shameless performances they’d ever seen from any group of lobbyists, and
that the “fact sheet” ... was, to quote one person familiar with the
situation, “disgraceful” and “hilarious.” ...
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 12:28 PM in Economics, Financial System, Politics, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (21)
David Warsh on Irving Kristol:
The Straw That Stirred the Drink, by David Warsh: Irving Kristol, who died
earlier this month at 89, meant many different things to many different people.
One way to remember him is as the editor who, with his friend and City College
of New York classmate Daniel Bell, founded The Public Interest in 1965,
at just the moment the phenomenon known as “the counterculture” was beginning to
grip the popular imagination of the West.
The first issue featured Robert Solow on “Technology and Unemployment,” Daniel
Patrick Moynihan on “The Professionalization of Reform,” Nathan Glazer on “The
Paradoxes of Poverty,” Jacques Barzun on “Art – By Act-of-Congress,” Daniel
Greenberg on “The Myth of the Scientific Elite,” Martin Diamond on
“Conservatives, Liberals and the Constitution,” and Daniel Bell on “The Study of
the Future.”
And for the next fifteen years, while the Americans lost their way in Vietnam,
the Soviet economy stagnated, the Chinese people suffered Mao Tse Tung’s
Cultural Revolution, The Public Interest was the quarterly that kept
its head, serving as a focal point for meliorists of all kinds. Magazines such
as People, Money and Rolling Stone built huge
audiences in those years; The Public Interest rarely sold more than
12,000 copies. But the people who read it would in due course take over the
nation’s politics.
An extraordinary galaxy wrote for Kristol in those days on nearly every social
issue of the day (Bell, a professor of sociology at Harvard, cut back his
participation after the two disagreed on the presidential election of 1972):
Peter Drucker, Milton Friedman, Seymour Martin Lipset, James Coleman, Robert
Nisbet, Henry Fairlie, Aaron Wildavsky, William Bennett, James Tobin, Richard
Zeckhauser, Thomas Schelling, Herbert Stein, Gordon Crovitz, Anthony Downs,
David Gordon, John Meyer, Jeffrey O’Connell, Paul Starr, Christopher Jencks,
Charles Reich, Michael Novak, Charles Lindblom, Josiah Lee Auspitz. They were
conservatives and liberals alike, but the quarterly’s content steadily trended
over the years towards the stance that in time would become known as
“neoconservative.” (A terrific full issue-by-issue archive can be found
here.)
Kristol “was able to pick a side without losing his clarity,” wrote David Brooks
in his New York Times column last week.
The side he picked in economics was an odd one. A 1975 issue featured a pair of
articles: “The Social Pork Barrel” launched the career of a young Michigan
Congressman, David Stockman, who would become budget director for Ronald Reagan;
and “The Mundell-Laffer Hypothesis – a New View of the World Economy,” by
Wall Street Journal editorial writer Jude Wanniski, introduced the world to
economists Arthur Laffer and Robert Mundell, and their newly-invented brand of
“supply side economics.”
The striking thing about Wanniski’s article was its anti-establishment tone,
anti-Chicago as well as anti-Cambridge, Mass. The new hypothesis might be as
transformative as the Copernican Revolution, he averred – or at least that of
John Maynard Keynes. Mundell and Laffer’s enthusiasms for a gold standard, fixed
exchange rates, large tax cuts and tight money were picked up and greatly
amplified by the editorial page of The Wall Street Journal. The
Republican Party was divided – insouciant economic populists in one wing, sober
technocrats in another.
In the neo-conservative firmament, the stars of ordinarily first-magnitude
conservatives Milton Friedman and Martin Feldstein dimmed, while Laffer and
Wanniski brightened. The success of The Way the World Works, Wanniski’s
1979 book for editor Midge Decter, nearly ripped apart the boutique social
science publisher Basic Books, where Kristol worked as an editor as well.
By then The Public Interest was losing its force. As James Q. Wilson
wrote the other day in The Wall Street Journal, “It began to speak more
in one voice and the number of liberals who wrote for it declined.” Daniel Bell
quietly resigned, in 1980. It didn’t matter. The Republicans were in power; and
Kristol was ready for a second act. He would become widely known as “the
Godfather” of neo-conservatism, dispensing favors and advice as a political
activist operating out of the American Enterprise Institute in Washington.
In its obituary last week, The Economist summed up this second act of
Kristol’s career: “American conservatism, before he began to shake it up, was
dour, backward-looking, anti-intellectual and isolationist, especially when
viewed from the east coast. By the time Mr. Kristol … had finished with it, it
was modern and outward looking, plumped up with business-funded fellowships and
think tanks and taking the lead in all policy debates.”
Success profoundly changed the game. The Cold War ended. The discipline and
sense of fair play seemed to go out of civic life. There hasn’t been anything
like The Public Interest since. But for fifteen crucial years in the
late ’60s and ’70s, Kristol’s editing was the straw that stirred the
drink.
I'm running short on time, so I'll leave the commentary to all of you, but I will note this:
Irving Kristol explains where the economics articles he published in The Public Interest came from:
Among the core social scientists around The Public
Interest there were no economists.... This explains my own rather
cavalier attitude toward the budget deficit and other monetary or
fiscal problems. The task, as I saw it, was to create a new majority,
which evidently would mean a conservative majority, which came to mean,
in turn, a Republican majority - so political effectiveness was the
priority, not the accounting deficiencies of government...
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 12:33 AM in Economics, Politics |
Permalink
Comments (7)
Simon Johnson and James Qwak wonder how much political capital the
administration is willing to use to meaningfully reform the financial system:
It's Crunch Time: The Fight to Fix the Financial System Comes Down to This, by
Simon Johnson and James Kwak, Commentary, Washington Post: The next couple
of months will be crucial in determining the shape of the financial system for
decades to come. And so far, the signs are not encouraging.
The Obama administration is trying to refocus our attention on regulation,
beginning with the president's speech in New York two weeks ago. ... Barney
Frank, chairman of the House Financial Services Committee, says that he still
plans to pass a regulatory reform bill before the end of the year.
But in a clear indication of trouble ahead, Frank signaled his intention last
week to scale back the proposed Consumer Financial Protection Agency, one of the
pillars of the administration's reform proposals. ...
We have criticized the administration's reform proposals, in particular for not
going far enough to address the problem of financial institutions that are "too
big to fail." But we support much of what was in the original package... The
question now is how hard Obama and Geithner will fight for it.
Financial regulation, like health care reform, has entered the phase where
speeches and proposals matter less than arm-twisting and horse-trading on
Capitol Hill. With health care, President Obama attempted to go over the heads
of Congress, directly to the American people. With financial regulation, that is
no longer an option, given the extent to which it has faded from public
consciousness. Instead, the administration is playing on the home turf of the
banking industry and its lobbyists. ... Is Obama up for this fight? ...
Elections have consequences, people used to say. This election brought in a
popular Democratic president with reasonably large majorities in both houses of
Congress. The financial crisis exposed the worst side of the financial services
industry to the bright light of day. If we cannot get meaningful financial
regulatory reform this year, we can't blame it all on the banking lobby.
The initial bill needs to be as strong as possible, and I agree that the administration needs to do what it can to prevent the bill from being scaled back. However, the initial legislation won't be as strong as I'd like even if the administration does prevail. But I hope we aren't thinking that we'll take one stab at financial reform and
then we'll be done with it. Like climate change and health care, it will require
a series of bills to achieve effective reform.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 12:15 AM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (6)
Chris Dillow says the British TV show
Come
Dine with Me "raises important issues about the nature of rationality and
preferences":
Come Dine With Me: the economics, by Chris Dillow: It’s insufficiently
appreciated that Come Dine with Me raises some profound issues in economics.
Here are three:
1. The importance of norms of fairness. The format of CDWM is simple.
There are four people. Each hosts a dinner party for the other three. The guests
score their host out of 10. The person with the highest score wins £1000.
In this game, the optimum strategy for a guest is to score their hosts zero.
This would mean the maximum score one’s rival hosts could make would be 20,
which in a normal game would not usually be sufficient to win. So, if your three
rivals play normally, scoring them zero greatly increases your chances of
winning.
If everyone knows this, we end up in a
Nash equilibrium in
which everyone scores zero; this is a one-shot game with scores revealed only
after all four dinner parties, so
tit-fot-tat doesn‘t
apply.
But this never happens. Even contestants who claim to want to win score their
rivals reasonably. This suggests that norms of fairness overwhelm selfish
optimization*.
This raises the question, though: why is CDWM so different from
Golden Balls - which is a pure
Prisoners‘ Dilemma game - where we often see the selfish defect-defect strategy?
The answer, I suspect, lies in the
abundance
effect. The difference between CDWM and Golden Balls is that in the latter
money is much more salient. And
research (pdf)
shows that, the more people think about money, the more selfish they behave.
The lesson is that context - not just incentives - matter.
2. The trickiness of inter-personal comparisons of utility. Let’s
assume that games are scored purely according to perceptions of fairness. It
doesn’t follow that everyone has an equal chance.
Continue reading ""Come Dine with Me: The Economics"" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 29, 2009 at 12:08 AM in Economics |
Permalink
Comments (7)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 28, 2009 at 11:05 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (37)
Paul Krugman on
Crowding In:
I’m at two deficit conferences Wednesday ... on what
to do about the deficit,...[and] why we need to run
deficits now. I’m trying to organize my thoughts...
Why, exactly, do we think that budget deficits are a bad thing? The textbook answer identifies two reasons — two ways in which budget
deficits now make us worse off in the future. They are:
(1) The fiscal burden: deficits now mean higher debt later, which will
have to be serviced, and that means higher taxes and/or less spending on
other, presumably desirable things.
(2) Crowding out: when it runs deficits, the government competes with
the private sector for funds, so deficits crowd out private investment,
which reduces potential growth
All this makes sense under normal conditions. But right now we’re not
living under normal conditions. We’re in a situation in which the
economy is deeply depressed, and monetary policy — the usual line of
defense against recession — is hard up against the zero-interest-rate
bound. This weakens argument (1) — and it actually reverses argument
(2).
On argument (1): it’s still true that an increase in government spending
raises future debt. But not one for one: because higher spending raises
GDP, it leads to higher revenue, which offsets a significant fraction of
the initial outlay. A back-of-the-envelope calculation suggests
something like a 40 percent offset is plausible, so fiscal stimulus only
costs 60 percent of what it costs.
But the really dramatic difference is for argument (2). Under the kind
of conditions we’re now facing, the main determinant of business
investment is the state of the economy, as evidenced by the plunge in
investment shown in the figure. This, in turn, means that anything that
improves the state of the economy, including fiscal stimulus, leads to
more investment, and hence raises the economy’s future potential.
That is, under current conditions deficit spending doesn’t lead to
crowding out — it leads to crowding in. In fact, you could argue that
the worst thing we can do for future generations is NOT to run
sufficiently large deficits right now.
Things won’t always work this way. Eventually we’ll emerge from the
liquidity trap, and the normal rules of economic prudence will reassert
themselves. But we are not there, or anywhere close to there, right now.
Let me also suggest:
Crowding-Out and Crowding-In. Here's the bottom line:
...Let us summarize what we have learned ... about the crowding-out
controversy.
• The basic argument of the crowding-out hypothesis is sound: Unless the
economy produces enough additional saving, more government borrowing will
force out some private borrowers, who are discouraged by the higher interest
rates. This process will reduce investment spending and cancel out some of the
expansionary effects of higher government spending.
• But crowding out is rarely strong enough to cancel out the entire
expansionary thrust of government spending. Some net stimulus to the economy
remains.
• If deficit spending induces substantial GOP growth, then the crowding-in
effect will lead to more saving-perhaps so much more that private industry can
borrow more than it did previously, despite the increase in government
borrowing.
• The crowding-out effect is likely to dominate in the long run or when the
economy is operating near full employment. The crowding-in effect is likely to
dominate in the short run, especially when the economy has a great deal of
slack.
• Surpluses have just the opposite effects. When slack exists, they are
likely to slow growth by reducing aggregate demand. But in the long run, budget
surpluses are likely to foster capital formation and speed up growth.
And finally, see also ZIRP Deficits cause Crowding In of Investment, by reducing Deflation.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 28, 2009 at 01:53 PM in Budget Deficit, Economics |
Permalink
Comments (35)
Robert Reich says of the public option for health care insurance, "yes we can," even if it means
overriding the promises of the person identified with the phrase:
The Public Option Lives On, by Robert Reich: Tomorrow (Tuesday) is a critical day in the saga of the public option. Democrats
Charles Schumer ... and Jay Rockefeller ... are introducing
an amendment to include the public option in the bill to be reported out by the
Senate Finance Committee -- the committee anointed by the White House as its
favored vehicle for getting health care reform.
Before you read another word, call and email the Senate offices of Democrats Max
Baucus (Montana), Tom Carper (Delaware), Robert Menendez (New Jersey), Kent
Conrad (North Dakota), and Ben Nelson (Florida) -- telling them you want them to
vote in favor of the public option amendment. And get everyone you know in these
states to do the same. Hell, you might as well phone and email Republican
Olympia Snowe (Maine) and make the same pitch.
Background: Every dollar squeezed out of Big Pharma and Big Insurance is a
dollar less that you'll have to pay ... to
cover healthcare costs. The two most direct ways to squeeze future profits are
allowing Medicare to use its huge bargaining leverage to negotiate lower drug
prices, and creating a public insurance option to compete with private insurers...
Continue reading ""The Public Option Lives On"" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 28, 2009 at 11:08 AM in Economics, Health Care, Politics |
Permalink
Comments (33)
Why aren't people getting hot under the collar about climate change?:
Cassandras of
Climate, by Paul Krugman, Commentary, NY Times: Every once in a while I feel
despair over the fate of the planet. If you’ve been following climate science,
you know what I mean: the sense that we’re hurtling toward catastrophe but
nobody wants to hear about it or do anything to avert it.
And here’s the thing: I’m not engaging in hyperbole. These days, dire warnings
aren’t the delusional raving of cranks. They’re what come out of the most widely
respected climate models... The prognosis for the planet has gotten much, much
worse in just the last few years.
What’s driving this new pessimism? Partly it’s the fact that some predicted
changes, like a decline in Arctic Sea ice, are happening much faster than
expected. Partly it’s growing evidence that feedback loops amplifying the
effects of man-made greenhouse gas emissions are stronger than previously
realized. For example,... global warming will cause the tundra to thaw,
releasing carbon dioxide, which will cause even more warming, but new research
shows far more carbon dioxide locked in the permafrost than previously thought,
which means a much bigger feedback effect.
The result of all this is that climate scientists have, en masse, become
Cassandras — gifted with the ability to prophesy future disasters, but cursed
with the inability to get anyone to believe them.
And we’re not just talking about disasters in the distant future... The really
big rise in global temperature probably won’t take place until the second half
of this century, but there will be plenty of damage long before then.
For example, one 2007 paper in the journal Science ... reports “a broad
consensus among climate models” that a permanent drought, bringing Dust
Bowl-type conditions, “will become the new climatology of the American Southwest
within a time frame of years to decades.” ...
In a rational world, then, the looming climate disaster would be our dominant
political and policy concern. But it manifestly isn’t. Why not?
Part of the answer is that it’s hard to keep peoples’ attention focused. Weather
fluctuates..., any year with record heat is normally followed by a number of
cooler years...
But the larger reason we’re ignoring climate change is that Al Gore was right:
This truth is just too inconvenient. Responding to climate change with the vigor
that the threat deserves would not, contrary to legend, be devastating for the
economy as a whole. But it would shuffle the economic deck, hurting some
powerful vested interests even as it created new economic opportunities. And the
industries of the past have armies of lobbyists in place...; the industries of
the future don’t.
Nor is it just a matter of vested interests. It’s also a matter of vested ideas.
For three decades the dominant political ideology in America has extolled
private enterprise and denigrated government, but climate change ... can only be
addressed through government action. And rather than concede the limits of their
philosophy, many on the right have chosen to deny that the problem exists.
So here we are, with the greatest challenge facing mankind on the back burner,
at best, as a policy issue. I’m not, by the way, saying that the Obama
administration was wrong to push health care first. It was necessary to show
voters a tangible achievement before next November. But climate change
legislation had better be next.
And as I pointed out in my last column, we can afford to do this..., economic
modelers have been reaching consensus ... that the costs of emission control are
lower than many feared.
So the time for action is now. O.K., strictly speaking it’s long past. But
better late than never.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 28, 2009 at 01:03 AM in Economics, Environment |
Permalink
Comments (72)
James Surowiecki interviews Joseph Stiglitz about "the mishandling of the
financial crisis, the relationship between government and markets, and the
future of capitalism around the world."
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 28, 2009 at 12:47 AM in Economics, Financial System, Market Failure |
Permalink
Comments (5)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Sunday, September 27, 2009 at 11:03 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (14)
Robert Shiller defends financial innovation:
In defense of financial innovation, by Robert Shiller, Commentary, Financial
Times: Many appear to think that the increasing complexity of financial
products is the source of the world financial crisis. In response to it, many
argue that regulators should actively discourage complexity. ... They do have a
point. Unnecessary complexity can be a problem ... if the complexity is used to
obfuscate and deceive, or if people do not have good advice on how to use them
properly. ...
But any effort to deal with these problems has to recognize that increased
complexity offers potential rewards as well as risks. New products must have an
interface with consumers that is simple enough to make them comprehensible, so
that they will want these products and use them correctly. But the products
themselves do not have to be simple.
The advance of civilization has brought immense new complexity to the devices we
use every day. ... People do not need to understand the complexity of these
devices, which have been engineered to be simple to operate.
Financial markets have in some ways shared in this growth in complexity, with
electronic databases and trading systems. But the actual financial products have
not advanced as much. We are still mostly investing in plain vanilla products
such as shares in corporations or ordinary nominal bonds, products that have not
changed fundamentally in centuries.
Why have financial products remained mostly so simple? I believe the problem is
trust. ... People are ... worried about hazards of financial products or the
integrity of those who offer them. ... When people invest for their children’s
education or their retirement, they ... may not be able to rebound from mistaken
purchases of faulty financial devices...
Thus, to facilitate financial progress, we need regulators who ensure trust in
sophisticated products. ... They must ... be open to ... complex ideas ... that
have the potential to improve public welfare.
Unfortunately, the crisis has sharply reduced trust in our financial system...,
people do not trust some good innovations that could protect them better. ... I
have proposed ... “continuous workout mortgages”...[to] protect against
exigencies such as recessions or drops in home prices. Had such mortgages been
offered before this crisis, we would not have the rash of foreclosures. Yet,
even after the crisis, regulators seem to be assuming a plain vanilla mortgage
is just what we need for the future. ...
Another innovation that is underused is retirement annuities... There are ...
annuities that protect people against outliving their wealth,... that protect
against inflation,... that protect against having problems in old age... and
generational annuities that exploit the possibilities of intergenerational risk
sharing. But most people do not make use of any of these.
Ideally, all of these protections for retirement income should be rolled into a
unified product. Such products are not generally available yet. Certainly,
people might be mistrustful of committing their life savings to such a complex
new product at first even if it were available. So, such products are not
offered and people often do nothing to protect themselves against most of these
risks.
Behind the creation of any such new retail products there needs to be an
increasingly complex financial infrastructure... It is critical that we take the
opportunity of the crisis to promote innovation-enhancing financial regulation
and not let this be eclipsed by superficially popular issues. ... Regulatory
agencies need to be given a stronger mission of encouraging innovation. ...
Something has to assure people that these product are safe before they will
purchase them. We might have expected the market to regulate risk not so long
ago, and trusted it to do so, but that seems like a bad bet now. An "interface
with consumers that is simple enough to make [the products] comprehensible"
could build trust if people could believe that the person doing the simplifying
had considered and understood every possible risk that is attached to the
product, but did anybody really comprehend the big picture in our most recent
crisis? If there were such people, there weren't very many of them, not enough
to inspire confidence and trust more generally.
Another method of building confidence is ratings agencies, but they won't be
trusted again any time soon. Regulators that make the public confident that
nothing can go wrong would help too, but building that kind of trust in
regulators after what just happened is a tall order. Private insurance of some
sort is an option, but absent some sort of government guarantee, can private
insurance companies be trusted with your life savings if there is a severe
financial meltdown? People have even lost faith in government's ability to
insure people against medical and financial calamity in old age, so when it
comes to providing financial insurance, government is not the solid, trusted
institution it was not so long ago.
As you tick down the list of ways trust might be restored, you find one
failure after another in terms of providing reliable information on the risks of
particular financial products or strategies, and no matter what regulators or
anyone else tries to do to rebuild the trust in financial institutions and
products that has been lost, recent track records make it likely that this will
be a long, drawn out process. Given that forgetting about such risks over time
seems to be an ingredient in the development of bubbles, I'll let you decide
whether that's good or bad.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Sunday, September 27, 2009 at 03:33 PM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (23)
Barkley Rosser:
Washington Post Puffs Gold Buggery, by Barkley Rosser: The business section
of today's Washington Post contains one of the most ridiculous news stories I
have seen yet. I would not mind if this were a column, but "What's Making Gold a
Hot Commodity" by Frank Ahrens is supposedly a news story, and as such it should
not contain whoppingly erroneous statements without some correction. So, Ahrens
himself says the following: "In the long term, with each new dollar introduced
into the system, each dollar you hold becomes worth less. That's more than just
inflation, which we think of as simply rising prices. That's debasement of not
only our currency, but the globe's reserve currency." It may well be that
nonsensical thinking such as has this pushed the price of gold back over $1,000
per ounce again, but why should a business section reporter repeat it without
the slightest doubt. It is not even good monetarism, as monetarists only view
money supply expansions beyond growth of real output and not offset by velocity
changes as inflationary.
A bit later, Ahrens uncritically quotes Peter Boockvar, an equities trader at
Miller Tabak: "It amazes me that any self-respecting central banker is not
alarmed that gold is over $1,000 an ounce and the dollar is trading at all-time
record lows." All-time record lows? Only against gold. Currently the dollar is
about 1.46 against the euro, while it hit 1.5990 in July 2008. It is around 92
against the yen, but in 1995 got as low as 79.95. It is a bit over 1.5 against
the pound, but was at 1.98 last year (and further back in history was over 4.0).
Utter drivel.
I do recognize that later in the article Ahrens brings up some factors that
might caution people a bit against buying gold too frenziedly, such as how much
of it is held by central banks, and how little demand for it is due to
industrial use (only about 10%). But he never mentions that it has already been
above $1,000 twice before, only to fall back, and in the late 1970s was much
higher in real terms, at well over $800, only to fall very far below that and
stay well below that for decades. The warnings could have been a bit clearer,
along with avoiding mindlessly repeating totally ridiculous non-facts spouted by
wacko gold bugs.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Sunday, September 27, 2009 at 01:13 PM in Economics, Inflation |
Permalink
Comments (73)
Stephen Ziliak emails:
Only moralists and economists know that Adam Smith's Theory of Moral Sentiments
(1759) turned 250 years old this year.
However worthy an Adam Smith party, I thought you'd like to know about another
party and sentiment, "Arthur's Day" - the
Guinness
Brewery's 250th birthday party - to be celebrated Thursday, September 24th,
all over the world:
My article, "Great Lease, Arthur Guinness - Lovely Day for a Gosset!" (prepared
for a special "Beeronomics" issue of
the Journal of Wine Economics), shows how clever counting at Guinness did not
stop two and a half centuries ago when Arthur signed a 9,000 year lease for the
brewery, house, and land at St. James's Gate in exchange for 45 pounds a year
(nominal, not inflation adjusted)!
"The great innovation in statistics in the era after Galton and Pearson was made
in the private sector of the economy, between 1904 and 1937, at Guinness's
Laboratory, to the end of improving, however gradually, production of a
consistent beer at efficient economies of scale" (Ziliak 2009, p. 4).
Here's the article "Great Lease, Arthur Guinness—Lovely Day for a Gosset!":
HTML clipboardAbstract: Small sample theory—the great innovation in statistical
method in the period after Galton and Pearson—was ironically discovered by a
brewer during routine work performed at a large brewery, Arthur Guinness, Son &
Company, Ltd. For four decades William S. Gosset applied small sample
experiments to the palpable end of improving, however gradually, the production
and control of a consistent unpasteurized beer when packaged and sold at
efficient economies of scale. Introducing, "Guinnessometrics." Annual output of
stout at Guinness’s Brewery may have topped 100 million gallons but Gosset’s
scientific knowledge was built one barleycorn at a time; in fact, the inventor
of small sample theory worked closely with botanists and breeders. In the
process, the brewer, William Sealy Gosset (1876-1937) aka "Student," an
Oxford-trained chemist—though self-trained in statistics—solved a problem in the
classical theory of errors which had eluded statisticians from Laplace to
Pearson. In addition, though few have noticed, Gosset’s exacting theory of
errors, both random and real, marked a significant advance over ambiguous
reports of plant life and fermentation asserted by chemists from Priestley and
Lavoisier down to Pasteur and Johannsen, working at the Carlsberg Laboratory.
Central to the Guinness brewer’s success was his persistent economic
interpretation of uncertainty, what Ziliak and McCloskey (2008) call the "size
matters/how much" question of any series of experiments. An enlightened change
in Guinness human resources policy gave an incentive structure that also seems
to have nudged "Student," who rose in position to Head Brewer, to find a profit
when the opportunity knocked. Beginning in 1893, Guinness vested "scientific
brewers" such as Gosset with managerial authority. In fact Gosset was at times
involved with price negotiations over hundreds of tons of barley and
hops—perhaps hours or minutes before he ran (that is, calculated) a regression
on related material. In brewing circles William Gosset is remembered less
nowadays than he might be. He did not give two cents for arbitrary rules about
statistical significance—at the 5% level or any level arbitrarily assumed. How
the odds should be set depends on the importance of the issues at stake and the
cost of getting new material, he said from 1904. Yet even in brewing journals,
both academic and trade, and for the past 85 years, statistical significance at
the 5% level continues to draw its arbitrary line segregating a meaningful from
a non-meaningful result, a better barley from a worse.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Sunday, September 27, 2009 at 10:35 AM in Academic Papers, Economics |
Permalink
Comments (2)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Saturday, September 26, 2009 at 11:03 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (16)
Bruce Bartlett and Barry Ritholtz on Ron Paul's call for the Fed to be audited:
Auditing the Fed, by Bruce Bartlett: Ron Paul finally got his wish yesterday
and the House Financial Services Committee held a hearing on his legislation to
audit the Federal Reserve. There were only two witnesses: the Fed's general
counsel and Tom Woods, a historian from the Ludwig von Mises Institute. The
testimony is available
here.
I urge those curious about this issue to read both statements. I think it is
abundantly clear that this is a crackpot idea. The Fed is already thoroughly
audited in every area except two: monetary policy and dealings with foreign
central banks. The only purpose of having additional audits of the Fed is to
undermine its independence precisely with regard to these two areas. If Woods
presents the best argument for doing so, the argument is very shallow indeed.
Whatever one thinks of the Fed's policies in recent years--and there certainly
are grounds for criticism--there is no reason whatsoever to believe that
undermining its independence and putting the Congress in control of monetary
policy--Ron Paul's goal--would improve matters at all. Indeed, there is every
reason to believe that full congressional control of monetary policy would be a
disaster. Instead of getting Switzerland-like stability, as Paul foolishly
imagines, the more likely result would be Zimbabwe-like hyperinflation.
In the end, I agree with Barry Ritholz that whatever the Fed's failings, those
of Congress are vastly worse. As he
put it in explaining why he didn't testify yesterday:
I was invited to testify this week to the House Financial Services Committee
about reform and regulation.
I politely demurred.
While I have been critical of the Federal Reserve (especially the Greenspan
years), my beef with them has been their judgment and decision-making process.
Congress, on the other hand, is a whole different matter. Its not their
judgment, but rather, the fact they are owned not by the American people, but by
lobbyists, and corporate interests. They have become structurally deformed.
How weird is it for me, who spent so many pages blaming the Fed for a lot of
the recent crisis, to find myself in a position of defending them from outside
political pressure? The choice we face is the recent Fed regime of secrecy,
nonfeasance, irresponsibility, and easy money — versus something
possibly likely to be a
whole lot worse. ...
If the Fed has been a major source of problems, Congress is much worse. They
were the great enablers of the crisis, readily corruptible, bought and paid for
by the banking industry. I find Congress to be the worse of two evils — lacking
in objectivity, incapable of producing legitimate regulatory review. ...
As I've made clear in the past, I also think that auditing the Fed, or reducing its independence in other ways, is a bad
idea. The strange marriage of the populists and libertarians on this issue has
given it more momentum that I expected, but hopefully not enough to carry the
day.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Saturday, September 26, 2009 at 11:11 AM in Economics, Monetary Policy, Politics |
Permalink
Comments (90)
Ezra Klein interviews Barney Frank about financial reform:
Barney Frank Talks Back, Washington Post: ...What's the most important
part of financial regulation?
Limiting securitization. I believe the single biggest issue here is that people
invented ways to lend money without worrying if they got paid back or not by
securitizing the loan. ...
Do you worry that the banks that are "too big to fail" have gotten even
bigger?
Banks do fail. Wachovia failed. The problem is not banks but non-banks. The
answer is: We will be restricting their activities. They will not be as big, as
they will need much more capital. And if they do get big, they will not be so
leveraged. It's not the size of the institution that's the issue, it's the
amount of leverage.
Sen. Dick Durbin recently said that the big banks "frankly own the
place" after they killed "cramdown" bankruptcy legislation in the Senate. Won't
banks brush off financial regulation reform?
No. The big banks have been somewhat discredited. That's why the credit card
bill went in pretty easily over their objections. I believe reining in
derivatives and reducing leverage at high levels will be somewhat easy to do.
What killed the primary-residence bankruptcy bill [cramdown] was not the big
banks but the community banks and credit unions. They do have a lot of clout.
And they have a legitimate grievance: They have not been behind the abuses. If
we only had community banks and credit unions, we wouldn't be in this problem.
And it's important to note that they're not just powerful because they have
money, but because they're in everybody's district, and they're responsible and
thoughtful citizens.
So you think the big banks really have lost their power on the Hill?
Look at the credit card bill. Small banks don't do credit cards. ...
Should the administration have started on financial regulation sooner?
No! They were busy. I understand the media always wants to have bad things to
say. But they were working on undoing where we were. They were working to put
liquidity back. The problem was that 2008 took longer to end than we thought it
would. It didn't really end till April of 2009. The early months of the Obama
administration were spent trying to dig out of the hole. Let me ask you a
question. What harm came from waiting?
The argument is that you won't get as much regulation because the banks are
stronger now.
That's nonsense. ...
Is executive compensation a big part of the problem?
Absolutely. The problem is not just the amount. Shareholders will deal with
that. It's the incentive. People had incentives to take risks because they got
paid off if the risk paid off and paid no penalty if the risk blew up. They were
taking risks free of the consequences of failure. Heads they won, tails they
broke even. ...
You became a YouTube celebrity a few weeks ago for snapping at a town hall
protester who held up a picture of Barack Obama with a Hitler moustache. You
said that arguing with her would be like debating a dining room table. Why don't
more of your colleagues yell back?
So the question is, you're asking me, who yelled back, why other people
don't yell back? ... I don't know. Ask them.
I hope he's right, but I expect the fight will be tougher than implied above. Just about everybody has a credit card, and lowering fees on the cards, etc., is an easy sell to legislators looking to gain or maintain votes. Other proposals may not enjoy the same broad based support and appeal, especially after lobbyists and others spin the legislation as opposed to the best interests of the very people the legislation is trying to protect.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Saturday, September 26, 2009 at 11:11 AM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (21)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Friday, September 25, 2009 at 11:03 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (4)
Bruce Bartlett reiterates his disappointment with Republican attitudes toward
taxes and the deficit:
Fiscal Responsibility Requires Higher Taxes, by Bruce Bartlett, Commentary,
Forbes: Throughout most of our nation's history,... everyone who thought of
themselves as a conservative believed absolutely in the necessity of balancing
the budget... Today, the notion seems quaint. Republicans pay lip service to balancing the
budget, but only when Democrats are in office. ... [T]he now-universal view
among conservatives [is] that ... taxes must never be raised to reduce deficits.
That's a cure worse than the disease...
This reversal of the historical conservative position has had enormous
implications for our national finances. ... The reason why conservatives supported a balanced budget in the first place
wasn't so much about the economics as a belief that it was a constraint on
spending and the growth of government. That deficits were inflationary, raised
interest rates and led to crowding out in financial markets, which reduced
economic growth, was really a secondary consideration.
A key reason why a balanced budget requirement constrained spending is that
deficits led to higher taxes. Since people don't like paying taxes, they put a
brake on spending that couldn't be financed out of current revenues. In the
event that there was some new program that was widely deemed to be desirable,...
it was commonly understood that new taxes dedicated just to these programs were
an essential requirement for enactment.
Programs that couldn't be financed weren't seriously considered until the Bush
43 administration. Contrary to the experience of Social Security and Medicare,
he offered no dedicated financing for the Medicare drug benefit. It simply added
to the budget deficit and will add as much to it over the next decade as the
February stimulus package that every Republican voted against.
And, of course, no effort was made to pay for tax cuts or pork barrel projects.
In fact, Republicans jettisoned PAYGO (pay as you go) budget rules in 2002. ...
When pressed about their abandonment of support for the balanced budget,
Republicans say that supporting higher taxes to reduce deficits only made them
tax collectors for the welfare state. ...
In the 1970s, conservatives talked themselves into believing that cutting taxes
was a better way of restraining government's growth than supporting a balanced
budget. Just take away Congress's credit card, Ronald Reagan used to say, and it
will be forced to cut spending.
This reversal of the long-held conservative position proved to be extremely
popular, politically, and had a lot to do with the Republican takeover of
Congress in 1994. It is now Republican dogma that taxes must never be increased
no matter how big the deficit. The last Republican to do that, Bush 41, got
thrown out of the White House..., Republicans believe. ...
During Bill Clinton's administration, Democratic economists got religion on
deficits. They believe that his 1993 tax increase sparked an economic boom. They
also saw that ... the federal budget [go] from deficit to surplus... Clinton's
big mistake was in not locking up the surpluses in some way. One idea would have
been to use the surpluses to create private Social Security accounts that
Republicans wouldn't have dared to touch any more than they would dare to cut
Social Security benefits.
Instead, the surpluses were completely dissipated on temporary tax cuts and
spending programs that bought reelection for Republicans in 2002 and 2004, but
made no lasting contribution to the economy's growth. Even as the surpluses
turned into deficits, Republicans' position didn't change--they were still for
big tax cuts...
Indeed, back in February when Congress was debating the stimulus package and the
Treasury was facing a deficit of $1.2 trillion this year, the Republican
position was that tax cuts--and only tax cuts--would stave off a deep recession.
How that would have helped when incomes were falling to such an extent that tax
revenues were virtually collapsing on their own was never explained. Tax cuts
were a mantra to be repeated endlessly whether they had any rational connection
to the economy's problems or not.
Everyone knows that fiscal discipline must be restored eventually, or we will
face truly horrifying consequences... Everyone also knows that this will involve
a combination of higher revenues and lower spending. The idea that we can
restore fiscal health only with spending cuts is childish, as I tried to explain
last week.
What we face is a game of chicken. Republicans think if they wait until the last
possible second to support the smallest possible tax increase necessary to make
a budget deal work, they can get the largest possible spending cuts. The problem
is that there is not one iota of historical evidence that this strategy will
work. The budget deals of the 1980s and 1990s were all roughly 50-50: half tax
increases, half spending cuts.
At some point, taxes have to be back on the table as the price that must be paid
for profligate spending. Only then will the American people realize that they
can't have their cake and eat it too, as Republicans have preached for the last
decade. Only when the American people go back to believing that spending must be
paid for will they stop demanding something for nothing and put the country back
on the path to fiscal sanity.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Friday, September 25, 2009 at 05:05 PM in Budget Deficit, Economics, Politics, Taxes |
Permalink
Comments (35)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Friday, September 25, 2009 at 09:43 AM in Economics |
Permalink
Comments (45)
The Waxman-Markey cap-and-trade climate bill won't destroy economic growth:
It’s Easy Being Green, by Paul Krugman:, Commentary, NY Times: So, have you
enjoyed the debate over health care reform? Have you been impressed by the
civility of the discussion and the intellectual honesty of reform opponents? If
so, you’ll love the next big debate: the fight over climate change.
The House has already passed a fairly strong cap-and-trade climate bill, the
Waxman-Markey act, which if it becomes law would eventually lead to sharp
reductions in greenhouse gas emissions. But on climate change, as on health
care, the sticking point will be the Senate. And the usual suspects are doing
their best to prevent action.
Some of them still claim that there’s no such thing as global warming, or at
least that the evidence isn’t yet conclusive. But that argument is wearing thin
— as thin as the Arctic pack ice... So the main argument against climate action
probably won’t be the claim that global warming is a myth. It will, instead, be
the argument that doing anything to limit global warming would destroy the
economy. ...
It’s important, then, to understand that claims of immense economic damage from
climate legislation are as bogus, in their own way, as climate-change denial.
Saving the planet won’t come free (although the early stages of conservation
actually might). But it won’t cost all that much either.
How do we know this? First, the evidence suggests that we’re wasting a lot of
energy right now...— a phenomenon known ... as the “energy-efficiency gap.” The
existence of this gap suggests that policies promoting energy conservation
could, up to a point, actually make consumers richer.
Second, the best available economic analyses suggest that even deep cuts in
greenhouse gas emissions would impose only modest costs on the average family.
Earlier this month, the Congressional Budget Office released an analysis of the
effects of Waxman-Markey, concluding that in 2020 the bill would cost the
average family only $160 a year, or ... roughly the cost of a postage stamp a
day.
By 2050, when the emissions limit would be much tighter, the burden would
rise... But the budget office also predicts ... that G.D.P. per person will rise
by about 80 percent. The cost of climate protection would barely make a dent in
that growth. And all of this, of course, ignores the benefits of limiting global
warming.
So where do the apocalyptic warnings about the cost of climate-change policy
come from?
Are the opponents of cap-and-trade relying on different studies that reach
fundamentally different conclusions? No, not really. ... Instead, the campaign
against saving the planet rests mainly on lies.
Thus, last week Glenn Beck — who seems to be challenging Rush Limbaugh for the
role of de facto leader of the G.O.P. — informed his audience of a “buried”
Obama administration study showing that Waxman-Markey would actually cost the
average family $1,787 per year. Needless to say, no such study exists.
But we shouldn’t be too hard on Mr. Beck. Similar — and similarly false — claims
about the cost of Waxman-Markey have been circulated by many supposed experts.
A year ago I would have been shocked by this behavior. But as we’ve already seen
in the health care debate, the polarization of our political discourse has
forced self-proclaimed “centrists” to choose sides — and many of them have
apparently decided that partisan opposition to President Obama trumps any
concerns about intellectual honesty.
So here’s the bottom line: The claim that climate legislation will kill the
economy deserves the same disdain as the claim that global warming is a hoax.
The truth about the economics of climate change is that it’s relatively easy
being green.
[See also
Can Countries Cut Carbon Emissions Without Hurting Economic Growth? by
Robert Stavins.]
Posted by Mark Thoma on Friday, September 25, 2009 at 12:24 AM in Economics, Environment |
Permalink
Comments (65)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Thursday, September 24, 2009 at 11:03 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (7)
Tim Duy is worried that the inflation hawks on the FOMC are gaining too much
influence (
Update: This was written before the WSJ editorial from Federal Reserve Governor Kevin Warsh
saying that the Fed may move faster and more aggressively than people expect, a statement that Tim anticipates in his comments below):
Rushing to the Exits?, by Tim Duy: A missive from a former colleague
prompted me to reconsider the Fed's behavior in light of their most recent
forecast and the evolution of economic data. That in
turn started to shed light on some little pieces of information sitting on my
computer that I knew were important, but just couldn't quite see how they fit.
And has left me somewhat concerned that the Fed may be more likely than I
believed to stifle the pace of the recovery by, at a minimum, halting the growth
of policy accommodation.
The Fed gave and took at the September FOMC meeting.
Policymakers reiterated support for their near zero rate policy, while
offering a slightly hawkish nuance that was noted by Jon Hilsenrath at the
Wall Street Journal:
Today’s Federal Open Market Committee statement included a nuanced tip of the
hat to hawks on the central bank’s policy making committee who think the Fed is
putting too much weight on the argument that the economy’s substantial slack
will drive down inflation.
Slack is the economy’s productive capacity that doesn’t get utilized —
unemployed workers, empty hotel rooms, unsold homes, idle factory floors, etc.
When there’s a lot of slack, it puts downward pressure on prices in the
short-run. It’s one very important reason why the Fed has felt comfortable
assuring markets that it is likely to keep interest rates exceptionally low for
a long time. Because slack is likely to keep inflation low, the Fed will keep
rates low.
But Fed officials have been engaged in an intense debate in recent months
about how much slack matters. Some hawks believe other factors are more
important ingredients in near-term inflation. One of those other factors is
inflation expectations — if investors, businessmen and consumers expect more
inflation, they could cause it by demanding higher prices and wages in
anticipation. The Fed indirectly acknowledged this argument in the September
statement: “With substantial resource slack likely to continue to dampen cost
pressures and with longer-term inflation expectations stable, the Committee
expects that inflation will remain subdued for some time.”
In previous recent statements, it hasn’t mentioned inflation expectations. It
focused mostly on slack. Here’s how the Fed put it in August: “Substantial
resource slack is likely to dampen cost pressures, and the Committee expects
that inflation will remain subdued for some time.”
The practical implication of this little wording change? Keep an eye on
measures of inflation expectations, such as inflation-protected Treasury bonds
and University of Michigan surveys of consumers. They have been stable. But if
they start rising, the Fed’s inflation view could change and tilt it toward a
more hawkish stance.
The shift in wording, then, appears to be the result of some more hawkish
FOMC members, illuminating the smidgen of truth
behind a rumor that was circulating earlier this month.
From
Across the Curve:
I was not planted here at my work station yesterday but roaming through the
myriad of emails I receive it seems that one of the reasons for the weakness
yesterday was a report by an advisory firm, Smick Medley, that the Federal
Reserve at its upcoming meeting would comment on and discus raising rates sooner
rather than later.
Given the FOMC's own forecast, any consideration of tightening seems silly:

While the Fed may find it necessary to raise the estimate of GDP growth for
this year on the back of a relatively sharp inventory correction, unemployment
is almost certain to exceed the range for this year, and even if it didn't, it
remains unacceptably high through 2011. Moreover,
the downward pressure on pricing has increased in recent months, bringing the
core-PCE forecasts into question:

On top of this, the concern of some hawks that inflation expectations will
suddenly trigger a wage price spiral seems simply silly unless one can explain
how, given current institutional arrangements in the US, price increase will
translate into wage increases. Indeed, unit labor
costs are giving you the exact opposite story:

And employment compensation for the private sector is likewise trending down:

Sure, one could turn to the commodity markets for inflation signals, but I
think the critical price there is oil, which is finding the $72 mark extremely
challenging to break through. That may have
something to do with reports that
quantity supplied to running well ahead of quantity demanded:
Crude oil declined for a second day in New York after a U.S. government
report showed a larger-than- expected increase in fuel stockpiles in the world’s
largest energy-consuming nation.
Gasoline stockpiles in the U.S. surged 5.4 million barrels last week, the
Energy Department said. That’s more than the 500,000-barrel increase forecast in
a Bloomberg News survey of analysts. Diesel and heating oil inventories jumped
2.9 million barrels, double what was expected. Crude oil supplies climbed 2.86
million barrels last week.
“The market has a glut of crude oil and refined products right now,” Victor
Shum, a senior principal at consultants Purvin & Gertz Inc. in Singapore, said
in a Bloomberg Television interview. “If we get a big correction in equities,
the loss of optimism in that demand recovery will continue to drive down
prices.”
And even if oil broke through the $72 mark, if $150 oil couldn't trigger a
wage-price spiral, what is $80 oil going to do? The
Fed's seeming eagerness halt monetary accommodation also runs in contrast to
forecasts that they really need to be doing much, much more to support growth.
From Goldman Sachs (no link):
In recent months, we have argued that the zero lower bound (ZLB) on nominal
interest rates represents a meaningful constraint on monetary policy in
particular and economic policy in general. Specifically, combining a variant of
the Taylor Rule for monetary policy with our forecast for growth and inflation,
we have long concluded that the Federal Open Market Committee (FOMC) would want
to push its target for the federal funds rate significantly below zero – to
levels of -6% or lower – if it had that option.
The -6% number suggests a much, much more aggressive expansion of the balance
sheet, while the Fed in contrast is willing to let the current programs play
themselves out over the course of the next six months.
So, given the unemployment outlook is sad, wage growth continues to
deteriorate, core inflation is falling, and we seem to lack an institutional
arrangement to force higher prices, should they even emerge, into higher wages,
what is the Fed thinking? Should they really be
worried about winding down programs? Are they really
confident enough that an inventory correction that will undoubtedly spike GDP
numbers will also translate into sustainable growth?
Even knowing full while that after the last recession, the US economy
languished despite the inventory correction, only to be revived on the back of
the housing bubble? In effect, the Fed looks to be
putting much weight on the cyclical story playing out, while ignoring the
structural story of the necessity of asset bubbles to fuel growth.
Pondering this, a little noticed
Bloomberg report jumped to mind:
Federal Reserve policy makers are concerned about making “a colossal policy
error” leading to higher inflation if they don’t withdraw extraordinary monetary
stimulus soon enough, said Laurence Meyer, vice chairman of Macroeconomic
Advisers LLC and a former Fed governor.
“When you talk to committee members you see a little bit more angst than
you’d expect,” Meyer said in an interview yesterday at the Kansas City Fed’s
monetary policy conference in Jackson Hole, Wyoming. “In public they say they’re
confident they’ll get it right, they’re confident they have the tools to get it
right. But when you talk to them in private there’s some concern there.”
So, added to the Medley rumor, the pieces start to fall together.
Internally, perhaps a wide range of FOMC members believe, in their hearts
if not in the data, that they have gone so far that the balance of risks have
shifted toward inflation. But this is troubling; the
basis for the inflation story falls entirely on the Fed's expansion of its
balance sheet. Just a meager $1.3 trillion
expansion give or take in the wake of an over $11 trillion decline in household
wealth? And the bulk of that expansion is sitting in
excess bank reserves? Not really much of an
inflation story. But why else are they so eager to
withdraw? Just to prove to critics they can?
With much fanfare, from
Bloomberg today:
The Federal Reserve and U.S. Treasury said they’re scaling back emergency
programs aimed at combating the financial crisis, reducing support for firms
that now have an easier time getting funding.
The central bank today said it will further shrink auctions of cash loans to
banks and Treasury securities to bond dealers, reducing the combined initiatives
to $100 billion by January from $450 billion. The Treasury has “begun the
process of exiting from some emergency programs,” the chief of the government’s
$700 billion financial-rescue fund said separately.
Bottom Line. The Fed is moving toward the exit as
they look toward the conclusion of their securities purchases programs.
But it is not clear that such a move is justified by their own forecasts
or the inflation/wage/employment data. There may be
an internal fear they have gone too far, a fear that the hawks can exploit. To
be sure, I see no reason to expect the Fed will raise rates for a long time.
And the Fed maintains it has policy flexibility, claiming to be ready to
revive asset purchases should economic or financial conditions justify.
But I now suspect the bar for renewed expansion of Fed accommodation may
be much higher than I had anticipated. And that the
dominant push for expansion would have to come from financial market conditions,
while they would be willing to tolerate persistently high unemployment rates so
long as U. Michigan inflation expectations say elevated, regardless of the
actual inflation data.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Thursday, September 24, 2009 at 03:33 PM in Economics, Fed Watch, Monetary Policy |
Permalink
Comments (100)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Thursday, September 24, 2009 at 08:46 AM in Economics, Health Care |
Permalink
Comments (12)
Jeffrey Sachs says our public management
systems need an overhaul:
The Failing U.S. Government--The Crisis of Public Management, by Jeffrey D.
Sachs, Scientific American: The crisis of American governance goes much deeper
than political divisions and ideology. The U.S. is in a crisis of policy
implementation. Not only are Americans deeply divided on what to do about health
care, budget deficits, financial markets, climate
change and more, but government is also failing to execute settled policies
effectively. Management systems linking government, business and civil society
need urgent repair.
The recent systems failures are legion and notorious. The 9/11 attacks might
well have been prevented if the FBI and the intelligence agencies had cooperated
more effectively... Hurricane Katrina caused mass devastation and loss of
life because recommendations to bolster the levees ... and
other protective measures were neglected for decades despite urgent expert
warnings, and because the federal emergency relief effort failed... The U.S.
occupation of Iraq was marked by massive ... corruption, incompetence,
and implementation failures by U.S. agencies.
On the economic front, the current financial crisis is a remarkable systems
failure. Government regulatory agencies completely dropped the ball...
The list, alas, goes on and on. Military procurement systems are ... broken... Public construction
systems are failing... Roads, bridges, rail, water and sewerage systems and many
dams are in dangerous disrepair...
We need a better scientific understanding of these pervasive systems failures.
It is wrong to think that they illustrate the inevitable failure of government.
Other governments around the world more successfully manage infrastructure
investments, health systems and environmental resources, apparently with greater
flexibility, less corruption, lower costs and better outcomes. America should be
learning from their experiences.
Several factors are at play. A key one has been the flawed privatization of
public-sector regulatory functions. ...
A second has been the collapse of planning functions within the federal
government. ...
A third, and paradoxical, factor is the chronic underfunding of government
itself. ... The public is wary of putting more funds
into government having witnessed one public sector failure after another. Yet
without investing more resources in skilled public managers in health care,
energy systems, and national security, we are probably doomed to remain stuck in
the hands of vested interests and lobbies.
Fourth, today’s challenges cut across technical specialties, government
departments and public and private sectors. ... Yet our government agencies are not designed to take a holistic
approach.
In short, we have arrived at a point where the challenges of sustainable
development —including public health, infrastructure, energy and national
security—require changes not only to policy but also to basic public management
systems. In many crucial areas, tinkering will no longer suffice: we need an
overhaul to regain government control over regulatory processes, reduce
lobbying, restore public planning and ensure the adequate financing of skilled
public managers, and align public management systems with holistic
strategies.
As evidenced by the response to the recent crisis, I'd add a fifth item to the list, opposition to the construction of the kinds of technocratic institutions that are needed to manage public systems:
Conservative Interventionism: The US government especially, but
other governments as well, have gotten themselves deeply involved in industrial
and financial policy during this crisis. They have done this without
constructing technocratic institutions like the 1930’s Reconstruction Finance
Corporation and the 1990’s RTC, which played major roles in allowing earlier
episodes of extraordinary government intervention into the industrial and
financial ... economy ... without an
overwhelming degree of corruption and rent seeking. The discretionary power of
executives, in past crises, was curbed by new interventionist institutions
constructed on the fly by legislative action.
That is how America’s founders ... envisioned that things would work. They were suspicious of executive power, and
thought that the president should have rather less discretionary power than the
various King Georges of the time. ...
So I wonder: why didn’t the US Congress follow the RFC/RTC model when authorizing George W. Bush’s and Barack Obama’s industrial and financial
policies? Why haven’t the technocratic institutions that we do have ... been given a broader role in this crisis?
Posted by Mark Thoma on Thursday, September 24, 2009 at 12:33 AM in Economics, Policy |
Permalink
Comments (30)
This is Nick Rowe (it's in response to Paul Krugman and follows up on one of Nick's previous posts):
Dark Age in Macroeconomics? A History of Taught approach, by Nick Rowe: (Or
maybe the title should be: "Notes from the
Phelps/Lucas Administration"; or "Notes to supplement our fading
memories of the late 1970's".)
Is this a
Dark Age in macroeconomics? In other words, have we collectively forgotten
some (important) stuff that we used to understand?
I want to approach this question by looking at what was taught in the past to
economics graduate students, so we can compare what is left out now to what was
left out then.
I have a sample of one: my own lecture notes from grad school. I began my MA
at UWO in 1977, and continued into the PhD. I took everything in macro/money
that was offered. At the time, UWO was arguably the top Canadian department
in macro/money (OK, Western grads would argue for; Queens grads would argue
against), and would hold up well against anywhere in the world.
Macro 1 (David Laidler). Required course. Review and critique of ISLM (lags,
stocks flows and the government budget constraint, are the IS and AD curves
really demand curves? [no], the missing AS curve). Crowding out debate. Non-Walrasian
macro (Barro and Grossman). Say's Law. Phillips Curve (up to Phelps and
Friedman). Consumption function (Friedman/Modigliani). Demand for money.
Investment demand.
Macro 2 (Michael Parkin). Required for those continuing to the PhD. (I can't
resist quoting from the first page of my notes here: "Economics [is]
Understand + Explain Phenomena using Rational models. How could Rational
Behaviour [lead to] Disaster? Market Failure."). Review and critique of
Neoclassical model of labour market. Lucas and Rapping (from the Phelps
volume), and why their model was logically incoherent (Michael Parkin was
right on this point). Mortensen's (also from Phelps volume) search theory of
unemployment. Theories of implicit wage contracts (sticky wages). Theories
of price adjustment (proto New-Keynesian). ISLM plus Phillips Curve
(distinction between proto New-Keynesian and New Classical interpretations
of Phillips Curve). Adaptive vs. Rational expectations. Policy Irrelevance
Proposition ("[deviations of output from y* are] just noise, but obviously
false").
Money 1 (Don Patinkin/Peter Howitt). Optional. Hume. Fisher. Lavington.
Wicksell. Keynes' Tract, Treatise, and General Theory. Patinkin's Money
interest and Prices. Are money and bonds net wealth? Commodity money.
Solow/Swan growth model. Money and growth. Optimal quantity of money.
Transactions costs. Baumol/Tobin and Miller/Orr models of demand for money.
Money 2 (Joel Fried). Optional. Microfoundations of money, Menger, Ostroy,
Jones. Money in general equilibrium theory. Clower constraints. Transactions
costs. Financial markets. Tobin. CAPM. Efficient Markets. Modigliani/Miller
theorem. Term structure of interest rates. Tobin portfolio choice. Friedman
and Monetarism. International finance. Dornbusch overshooting. Exogenous vs
endogenous money. Canadian monetary policy.
Advanced Macro (Peter Howitt). Optional. (Lovely quote from the first page:
"We are Aristotelian monks, trying to solve anomolies to stop future
generations wasting their time doing the same thing.". Non-Walrasian
disequilibrium theory (Clower, Leijonhufvud, Barro/Grossman, Malinvaud,
Benassy, etc.). Stability. Catastrophe theory(!). Price adjustment under
oligopoly. Optimal control theory. Inventories. Phelps/Winter price setting
with transient monopoly power (from the Phelps volume, proto New-Keynesian).
(I learned some more money/macro in David Laidler's History of Thought
class. But I was the only graduate student in that class, so I'm not going
to count it. My colleague Calum Carmichael, who took the same course as an
undergraduate, estimates that about one quarter of the Honours economics
students took that class.)
I make the follow observations:
1. The Phelps volume was clearly very influential in the late 1970's. This
supports Paul Krugman's memory, and my own.
2. The beginnings of the split between New Classical and New Keynesian
approaches was already apparent in the late 1970's. I saw several references
to the distinction between Fisher and Phelps on the interpretation of the
Phillips Curve. (Fisherian market-clearing with misperceptions vs Phelpsian
disequilibrium price adjustment). This too supports Paul Krugman's memory.
3. We received a very broad education in short run macroeconomics and
monetary theory. Probably much broader than today's students. That tends to
support the Dark Age hypothesis.
4. But there is one glaring omission from our education: we did lots of
short run business cycle theory but almost no long run growth theory. We
briefly covered the Solow growth model, but only as a prelude to money and
growth. There was no interest in growth theory per se! If growth theory is
important, and it is, that directly contradicts the Dark Age hypothesis. We
barely touched on half of macro! The late 1970's were the Dark Age, for
growth theory.
Why did we ignore growth theory?
Growth theory wasn't on the agenda. It wasn't that growth was unimportant;
just that there seemed to be nothing important to say about it. All the
exciting policy debates were about inflation and unemployment, not long run
growth. All the exciting theoretical developments were about inflation and
unemployment, not long run growth. "Endogenous" growth theories (a stupid
misnomer, because growth is endogenous in Solow too, just with an extremely
simple functional relationship to the exogenous variables, namely g=n) came
later.
Fiscal policy has been off the agenda for much the same reasons, until
recently.
(5. We spent surprisingly little time on open economy macroeconomics as
well, for a Canadian school.)
OK. Let's compare notes!
This is very similar to my own experience, we also did very little growth
theory (nothing beyond Solow-Swan, also as a prelude to looking at whether money was "superneutral"), and I didn't take any international at all -
it wasn't part of the macro sequence (the international economy was not considered very important for understanding business cycle fluctuations). The emphasis was on short-run stabilization policy, monetary policy in particular. However, my experience was a bit different in that
by the time I got to graduate school in the early 1980s, the split between saltwater and freshwater economists was well
underway.
Paul Krugman says:
But by 1980 or 1981 it was basically clear to everyone that the Lucas
project – the attempt to explain the evidently Keynesian behavior of
the economy in terms of nothing but imperfect information – had failed.
So what were macroeconomic theorists supposed to do?
The answer was that they split. One faction said, in effect, “OK: we
can’t explain what we think we see in terms of full maximization. So we
have to assume that there are some limits to maximization – costs of
changing prices, bounded rationality, whatever.” That faction became
New Keynesian, saltwater economics.
The other faction said, in effect, “OK: we can’t explain what we
think we see in terms of full maximization. So we must be interpreting
the data wrong – things like changes in the money supply must not be
driving recessions, because theory says they can’t.” That faction
became real business cycle, freshwater economics.
Here's what I
said about this just under two and a half years ago (edited slightly). As you can see, even though this was written well before Krugman's statement, it basically agrees with his assertion that everyone knew the New Classical model was in trouble by 1980 or 1981 (the Mishkin paper noted below was published, I believe, in 1982, but given the long publication lags the results were well known long before then). It also agrees with his comments that one faction, the New Keynesians, built upon the old Keynesian structure by giving it rational agents and microfoundations who operated in an environment beset with rigidities of one type or another (these rigidities prevent agents from fully neutralizing nominal shocks such as changes in the money supply), and the other faction reemerged as the real business cycle school:
I entered graduate school in 1980. Though it started with a pretty
traditional IS-LM framework with some AD-AS thrown in, most of our time was spent learning the New Classical model. Much of the research effort at that time, at least the effort I was
made aware of, was to try and punch holes in the result that comes out of the
New Classical framework that only unanticipated money can affect real variables
like output and employment.
This assault came on both theoretical and empirical fronts. Mishkin, for
example, had published an empirical paper in the early 1980s that challenged
work by Barro and others from the later 1970s supporting the New Classical model
and its implication that only surprise money matters. On the theoretical front,
the old Keynesian model -- which had been criticized for, among other things,
lacking microeconomic foundations and lacking rational expectations -- was being
reconstructed into the New Keynesian model. This model would eventually overcome
theoretical objections that plagued the older Keynesian model, and it would also
do a better job than the New Classical model of explaining the magnitude and
persistence of business cycles and other features of the macroeconomic data. We
learned some about Real Business Cycle models - but for the most part that work
went on elsewhere and would surface later with more force as an alternative to
the New Keynesian framework. But we were certainly made aware of the real business cycle model, e.g. arguments
about reverse causality to explain statistical money income correlations. I'd
say the same about growth theory - we did the Solow-Swan basics, but very little
beyond that. Stabilization policy was the main issue we worried about at the
time.
Does money matter? I thought so, that's what my dissertation was all about,
it gave theoretical and empirical reasons to doubt the New Classical result that
expected money does not affect output, but the issue of whether money matters
was not settled until later. We now accept, for the most part, that the Fed can
affect real interest rates and also affect the real economy, but at that time
there was a very strong split within the profession on this issue. It wasn't
until later that a general belief that anticipated monetary policy was a
potentially useful stabilization tool surfaced in the profession. It's sometimes
surprising to me today how complete the conversion on that issue has been,
though it's certainly not 100%.
So, it wasn't generally agreed that money mattered, i.e. that money was a
useful policy tool for stabilizing the real economy. But the Keynesian economics
I learned at the time, which was in the implicit and explicit labor contracting
framework for the most part, did say that money mattered. In fact, since the
point was to challenge the New Classical result that money did not matter, the
focus was mostly on monetary policy. As for fiscal policy, the Keynesian model
we talked about - beyond the simple IS-LM version we learned at first - paid
very little attention to fiscal policy, though papers such as Barro's "Are Bonds
Net Wealth" were part of the conversation. Thus, when I went to graduate school
- and this was partly due to who was teaching the courses - the primary focus was on whether and how
changes in monetary policy affected the real economy.
In any case, even though it was a few years later than Nick's experience, we also spent considerable time on the ideas that Krugman notes have since been lost as we entered our recent "Dark Ages."
Posted by Mark Thoma on Thursday, September 24, 2009 at 12:09 AM in Economics, Macroeconomics, Methodology |
Permalink
Comments (79)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 11:05 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (14)
I'm sorry, I really am. Here's the economics of apologies:
Saying sorry really does cost nothing, EurekAlert: Economists have finally
proved what most of us have suspected for a long time – when it comes to
apologizing, talk is cheap.
According to new research, firms that simply say sorry to disgruntled customers
fare better than those that offer financial compensation. The ploy works even
though the recipient of the apology seldom gets it from the person who made it
necessary in the first place.
The ... Nottingham School of Economics' Centre for Decision Research and
Experimental Economics ... set out to show whether customers who have been let
down continue to do business after being offered an apology. They found people
are more than twice as likely to forgive a company that says sorry than one that
instead offers them cash. ...
Continue reading "What's an Apology Worth?" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 05:47 PM in Economics |
Permalink
Comments (9)
Roman Frydman and Michael Goldberg argue that the behavioral assumptions used
to motivate agents in economic models need to change:
An economics of magical thinking,
by Roman Frydman and Michael D. Goldberg, Commentary, Economist's Forum: Confidence seems to be returning to markets almost everywhere,
but the debates about what caused the worst crisis since the Great Depression show no sign of letting up. Instead, the spotlight has shifted
from bankers, financial engineers and regulators to economists and their
theories. This is not a moment too soon. These theories continue to shape
the debate about fiscal stimulus, financial reform, and, more broadly, the future of capitalism, which means that they remain a danger to
all concerned.
Unfortunately, the assumptions that underpin these theories are
largely inscrutable to those without a Ph.D. in economics. Indeed, the debate is full of terms that mean one thing to the uninitiated and
quite another to economists.
Consider “rationality.”
Continue reading ""An Economics of Magical Thinking"" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 02:08 PM in Economics, Methodology |
Permalink
Comments (15)
[Money Watch link] After its rate setting meeting today, the Fed announced that it "will
maintain the target range for the federal funds rate at 0 to 1/4 percent," and
that it "continues to anticipate that economic conditions are likely to warrant
exceptionally low levels of the federal funds rate for an extended period." Very
few analysts thought the Fed should raise the rate, calls for higher rates came
from a few inflation hawks but that's about it, and nobody I know of expected
the Fed to change its interest rate policy. So no surprises here.
Of more interest are the Fed's characterization of economic conditions, its
plans for the special facilities and other non-standard monetary policy options
it has put in place to deal with the crisis, and its exit strategy.
Continue reading "As Expected, Fed Keeps Target Rate on Hold" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 12:16 PM in Economics, Monetary Policy |
Permalink
Comments (2)
At CBS Money Watch:
How should regulators be chosen?, by Mark Thoma
I argue that most people do not feel like their interests are represented when policy decisions are made about regulation, bailouts, and other matters, including decisions by the Federal Reserve on setting the target interest rate, and that needs to change.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 09:39 AM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (6)
There's not a populist bone in Robert Reich's body. Not a one:
Why the Dow is Hitting 10,000 Even When Consumers Can't Buy And Business Cries
"Socialism", by Robert Reich: So how can the Dow Jones Industrial Average be flirting with 10,000 when
consumers, who make up 70 percent of the economy, have had to cut way
back on buying because they have no money? Jobs continue to disappear. One out of six Americans
is either unemployed or underemployed. Homes can no longer function as piggy
banks because they’re worth almost a third less than they were two years ago.
And for the first time in more than a decade, Americans are now having to pay
down their debts and start to save.
Even more curious, how can the Dow be so far up when every business and Wall
Street executive I come across tells me government is crushing the economy with
its huge deficits, and its supposed “takeover” of health care, autos, housing,
energy, and finance? Their anguished cries of “socialism” are almost drowning
out all their cheering over the surging Dow.
The explanation is simple. The great consumer retreat from the market is being
offset by government’s advance into the market. Consumer debt is way down from
its peak in 2006; government debt is way up. Consumer spending is down,
government spending is up. Why have new housing starts begun? Because the Fed is
buying up Fannie and Freddie’s paper, and government-owned Fannie and Freddie
are now just about the only mortgage games remaining in play.
Why are health care stocks booming? Because the government is about to expand
coverage to tens of millions more Americans, and the White House has assured Big
Pharma and health insurers that their profits will soar. Why are auto sales up?
Because the cash-for-clunkers program has been subsidizing new car sales. Why is
the financial sector surging? Because the Fed is keeping interest rates near
zero, and ... the government is still guaranteeing any bank too big to
fail will be bailed out. Why are federal contractors doing so well? Because the
stimulus has kicked in.
In other words, the Dow is up despite the biggest consumer retreat from the
market since the Great Depression because of the very thing so many executives
are complaining about, which is government’s expansion. And regardless of what
you call it – Keynesianism, socialism, or just pragmatism – it’s doing wonders
for business, especially big business and Wall Street. Consumer spending is
falling back to 60 to 65 percent of the economy, as government spending expands
to fill the gap.
The problem is, our newly expanded government isn't doing much for average
working Americans who continue to lose their jobs and whose belts continue to
tighten, and who are getting almost nothing out of the rising Dow because they
own few if any shares of stock. Despite ... all their cries of "socialism" --
big business and Wall Street are more politically potent than ever.
It would have been better if the effort to revive the economy had a stronger
trickle up component, i.e. give the tax cuts or transfers to the people who need
it rather than those who don't, they will spend the extra money, it will trickle
up as profits to the owners of businesses as the money is spent and re-spent through the multiplier process, and the
owners will use the profits to hire more workers and to make productive
investments (and even if the money doesn't trickle up as expected, at least
you've helped people in need, when tax cuts for the wealthy don't trickle down,
the consolation prize isn't as attractive).
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 02:07 AM in Economics, Fiscal Policy |
Permalink
Comments (58)
Two from the Antonio Fatás and Ilian Mihov Global Economy blog. First, Antonio Fatás notes
cross-country differences in how productivity has evolved during the crisis, and
he speculates that the difference may be due to differences in how much effort
was devoted to reducing the impact of the recession on employment:
Output, employment and productivity during the crisis, by Antonio Fatás:
While most advanced economies have displayed significant drops in GDP during the
last years, the behavior of labor market variables (employment, unemployment,
number of hours) has been quite different across countries.
In countries such as the US or Spain we have seen a large decline in
employment/hours and the corresponding increase in unemployment. In countries
such as Germany or France or Sweden, employment and hours have fallen much less.
Below is data on labor productivity measured as GDP per hour worked in four
countries... In the case of Sweden and Germany we can see that the fall in GDP
has been much larger than the decrease in hours worked leading to a decline in
productivity. In the case of the US productivity has remained stable. In the
case of Spain the fall in employment and hours has been much larger than the
decrease in GDP which has produced a doubling of the productivity growth rates
in 2007/08 relative to the 2003-06 period.
Behind these figures we probably have a composition effect (different sectors
being affected differently by the crisis) but also different labor market
responses to the crisis, where in some cases there has been a conscious effort
to reduce the impact on employment.
Next, Ilian Mihov argues that consumer indebtedness might not be as bad as
you've been led to believe:
Household debt, consumption and wealth, by Ilian Mihov: It is very common
these days to hear that the global economy has no way of recovering because the
most powerful engine of global demand – the American consumer – is choking in
debt. ...
Indeed,... debt stands at $14.068 trillion or slightly less than 100% of GDP.
Does this mean that the economy is doomed? There are two points that one has to
take into account when evaluating the role of household debt in the economy.
1. Debt is only one side of the story. Households also own assets. Consumption
is a function of (net) wealth, not only of indebtedness. Up to a first
approximation what matters is the difference between assets and liabilities.
Indeed, no one thinks that a person with $10 million in debt is going to cut his
or her consumption, if you know that this person has $10 billion in assets. So,
how do American consumers fare in terms of net worth? Below is a graph with
three ratios – assets-to-GDP, debt-to-GDP and net-worth-to-GDP. Although
household debt stands at 100% of GDP, assets owned by US households currently
stand at $67.2 trillion or 475% of GDP. The net worth of the American households
is estimated to be over 375% of GDP.

Are these assets sufficient? This is hard to tell because theory does not
provide convincing guidance as to what the wealth-to-GDP ratio should be. But we
can look at the data to see how these numbers compare to historical averages.
The average ratio of US household net worth from 1952Q1 to 2009Q2 is about 350%
(if we exclude the two bubbles, the ratio is 330%). In short, US households
today have more net wealth than they had in normal times in the post WWII
period. Contrary to all complaints, US households today are richer than at any
point in time in the pre-1995 period (and again, this is relative to GDP; in
absolute terms no one will be surprised that this statement is true).
But maybe it is the composition of debt that matters – people today live off
their credit cards. It turns out that consumer credit has increased indeed over
the past 20 years but the numbers are not shocking. From about 14% in 1990,
consumer credit rose to 17.3% in 2009 (again the numbers are relative to GDP).
...
2. Even if we concede that debt can reduce consumption for an individual, it is
a bit trickier to make the same argument for the national economy. The reason is
that the liability of one individual is an asset for someone else. In the graph
above, the thin blue line is in fact included in the thick red line! ...
There are ways in which this “neutrality of debt” may break down. For example,
if those who are indebted have a higher propensity to consume than the lenders,
then debt will lead them to cut their consumption by more than the lenders will
increase theirs (due to the wealth effect). This is possible and even plausible,
but it is not clear whether empirically this effect is significant. Second, it
might be that household debt is held by foreigners. Again, the data are not very
supportive of this hypothesis because the net foreign asset position of the US
is not (yet) devastating – less than 20% of GDP.
In general, many other “imperfections” in the market economy can result in the
importance of debt for aggregate consumption, and I do agree that some of these
imperfections are realistic and important. The main point of the argument is
that we need a more nuanced view of why debt matters. We should keep in mind
that the net worth of US households is still quite high (375% of GDP) and that
debt should be viewed from a general equilibrium point of view and not only in
absolute terms.
One quick comment. This is hinted at in the second to last paragraph, but to make it more explicit, the distribution of assets and liabilities can matter, and given the rise in inequality over much of this time period (it coincides with the rise in the green and red lines beginning in the 1970s evident in the diagram above) along with the stagnant wages of the working class, there may well have been important distributional effects.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Wednesday, September 23, 2009 at 01:51 AM in Economics, Financial System, Productivity, Saving, Unemployment |
Permalink
Comments (26)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 22, 2009 at 11:01 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (31)
Bruce Judson says effective financial reform is essential to restoring trust
in government:
Restoring Trust in Our Economic System and the Institutions of Our Democracy, by
Bruce Judson: The Financial Crisis Inquiry Commission (FCIC), which started
work last week, will have a significant impact on the health of our democracy.
When the FCIC completes its efforts, we will either be stronger or weaker as a
nation. There is no middle ground. ...
The work of the Commission is important for two reasons. First, by openly
educating the public about the causes of the financial crisis it will pave the
way for reform. Existing interests will inevitably resist change. Reform becomes
far easier when its advocates can point to a roadmap of specific problems that
must be addressed. ...
Second, America is becoming an angry nation, with diminished faith in its
institutions. There is a growing sense among all but the wealthiest Americans
that
“the game is rigged” against them. The public perception of the work of the
FCIC will inevitably affect, for better or worse, our basic level of trust in
the nation’s democratic system.
Continue reading "Cynics, not Whiners?" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 22, 2009 at 04:23 PM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (11)
I have another post at CBS Money Watch:
Why We Need Plans To Break Up Too-Big-to-Fail Banks, by Mark Thoma
This reiterates that we need to have plans ready to dissolve systemically important financial firms. What I didn't say is that we should also do our best to
prevent firms from becoming a danger to the system due to their size of connectedness.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 22, 2009 at 09:46 AM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (21)
David Levine "aggressively
argues":
our models don't just fail to predict the timing of financial crises - they say
that we cannot.
The San Francisco Fed's Bharat Trehan says:
simple indicators based on asset market developments can provide early warnings
about potentially dangerous financial imbalances. ... [W]e have taken two simple indicators off the shelf and shown that both would have
signaled impending trouble prior to the current crisis. That makes it harder to
argue that financial crises are, by their nature, unpredictable. And it shows
that such simple indicators can be useful ... as signals of rising levels of risk in the economy.
See
here. Or
here.
We ought to be able to say, at the very least, something like:
If you keep eating that junky credit instead of a healthier financial diet, your
monetary circulatory system is likely to have severe problems at some point in
the future.
Many people had a sense things were out of balance and that at some point it
would cause us problems, but the indicators most people looked at pointed to a
diagnosis involving exchange rate movements and an international unwinding. The
discussion centered on issues such as whether we would have a
hard or a soft landing as this process unfolded, there was little discussion
of the type of crisis that actually occurred.
So we need two things. First, we need indicators such as those identified in
the SF Fed
article that can tell us when danger is building in the financial sector.
But that is not enough. Though many people had a sense from the indicators
they looked at that things were out of balance, the indicators pointed to
international financial issues rather than the true problem, and hence most of
the analysis and policy discussions were devoted to guarding against problems
related to international financial flows.
Thus, the second thing we have a need for is a set of indicators that do a better job of telling
us where the problems are likely to occur. That is where we made the biggest
mistake, misdiagnosing the type of crisis that was coming. Having indicators
that can do a better job of identifying the type of financial crisis we are
facing will allow us to design and implement effective policy responses rather
than wasting time analyzing and planning for the wrong type of crisis.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 22, 2009 at 12:49 AM in Economics, Financial System |
Permalink
Comments (54)
Tim Duy:
On the G20 Agenda, by Tim Duy: Simon Johnson at the Baseline Scenario has a
nice piece bemoaning the US pursuit of a rebalancing agenda at the upcoming
G20 meeting. I largely agree with Johnson's tone. Something that sounds nice,
but that to which no parties, particularly China and the US, can make a credible
commitment. It is, however, keeping some poor staffer at the US Treasury busy
24-7. Johnson's third point, however, misses some important points:
Where is the evidence that this kind of “imbalance” had even a tangential effect
on the build up of vulnerabilities that led to the global financial crisis of
2008-09? I understand the theoretical argument that current account
imbalances could play a role in a US-based/dollar crisis, but remember: interest
rates were low 2002-2006 because of Alan Greenspan (who controlled short-term
dollar interest rates); the international capital flows that sought out crazy
investments came from Western Europe, which was not a significant net exporter
of capital (i.e., a balanced current account is consistent with destabilizing
gross flows of capital); and the crisis, when it came, was associated with
appreciation – not depreciation – of the dollar.
I believe Johnson underestimates just how close we came to a destabilizing
collapse of the Dollar in 2008. That avoidance of that near collapse was well
documented by Brad Setser in his legendary "quiet
bailout" series:
...The US had a large external deficit going into the subprime crisis. That
means it has a constant need for external financing. Foreigners need to more
than just hold their existing claims on the US, they need to add to them. The US
responded to the subprime crisis with policies — a fiscal stimulus, monetary
easing — designed to support domestic US demand, not to assure ongoing demand
for US financial assets. And for a complex set of reasons – ongoing growth in
China, energy-intensive growth in the Gulf, limited expansion of supply and
perhaps monetary easing in the US — the price of oil has shot up even as the US
has slowed. Higher oil prices are likely to push the US trade deficit and the US
need for financing up — not down – at least in nominal terms.
So far that hasn’t been a serious problem. Central bank reserve growth has been
very strong, most because a couple of big countries are adding to their reserves
at an incredible rate. The New York Fed data tells us that a lot of that growth
has been channeled into safe US assets. But there are also growing signs that
rapid reserve growth is causing some countries — including some big countries —
trouble.
Later analysis can be found
here. Had it not been for the supporting role that China and other central
banks played in financing the US current account deficit, we would have seen a
full blown currency crisis, well before the financial crisis of September 2008.
As an aside, the intervention to support the Dollar was also the key event that
allowed the US recession to evolve in the pattern envisions by domestic-focused
economists, as opposed to those seeped in the traditions of international
finance. Brad Delong
has a fantastic piece on this issue, including the key assumption failed the
internationalists:
Before dinner one evening I was lectured by a prominent Washington-area
international finance economist about all the reasons that the 1986-1990 U.S.
experience was likely to be a bad guide to the future…
...The Japanese government was willing to buy very large amounts of
dollar-denominated assets in the late 1980s to keep the decline in the value of
the dollar "orderly." In so doing, it inflated its domestic credit base and
touched off its own property bubble. No foreign government is going to risk this
again just because the U.S. would rather that the decline in the dollar was slow
and orderly.
I have no doubt that the willingness of central banks to flood the global
economy with month in an effort to hold currency pegs contributed greatly to the
great commodity price bubble that ultimately sent US real consumption into a
tail spin well before the events in the fall of 2008.
As to the G20 proposal itself - easier said than done. Back on the real side of
the economy, I believe the US economy is very structurally misaligned, to a
disturbing degree. We simply do not make many of the products we want to buy,
and have the capacity to make many products - like expensive housing - that no
one wants to buy. Moreover, these structural misalignments have been building
for at least 15 years, at least partly the consequence of the US strong Dollar
policy that gave license for wholesale currency manipulation to support
mercantilistic policy objectives. Reversing 15 years of policy in which deep
structural shifts occurred will not happen overnight.
Nor do I think the Chinese are interested in making that transition happen.
Thomas
Freidman has a point here:
China now understands that. It no longer believes it can pollute its way to
prosperity because it would choke to death. That is the most important shift in
the world in the last 18 months. China has decided that clean-tech is going to
be the next great global industry and is now creating a massive domestic market
for solar and wind, which will give it a great export platform….So, if you like
importing oil from Saudi Arabia, you’re going to love importing solar panels
from China.
This restructuring, not so much the financial restructuring, is what I suspect
the Administration really wants to address.
Good luck with that.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Tuesday, September 22, 2009 at 12:33 AM in China, Economics, International Finance |
Permalink
Comments (53)
Larry Summers, blogging from the White House, says the administration's
policies will create jobs and help to ensure that "the entrepreneurial spirit that Schumpeter
recognized in the early twentieth century will continue to drive the American
economy":
A Vision for Innovation, Growth, and Quality Jobs, by
Lawrence H. Summers:
President Obama laid out his vision for innovation, growth, and quality jobs
earlier today at Hudson Valley Community College. The
President's plan is grounded not only in the American tradition of
entrepreneurship, but also in the traditions of robust economic thought.
During the past two years, the ideas propounded by John Maynard Keynes have
assumed greater importance than most people would have thought in the previous
generation. As Keynes famously observed, during those rare times of deep
financial and economic crisis, when the "invisible hand" Adam Smith talked about
has temporarily ceased to function, there is a more urgent need for government
to play an active role in restoring markets to their healthy function.
The wisdom of Keynesian policies has been confirmed by the performance of the
economy over the past year. After the collapse of Lehman Brothers last
September, government policy moved in a strongly activist direction.
As a result of those policies, our outlook today has shifted from rescue to
recovery, from worrying about the very real prospect of depression to thinking
about what kind of an expansion we want to have.
An important aspect of any economic expansion is the role innovation plays
as an engine of economic growth. In this regard, the most important
economist of the twenty-first century might actually turn out to be not
Smith or Keynes, but Joseph Schumpeter.
Continue reading ""A Vision for Innovation, Growth, and Quality Jobs"" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 21, 2009 at 11:11 PM in Economics, Fiscal Policy, Technology |
Permalink
Comments (31)
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 21, 2009 at 11:04 PM in Economics, Links |
Permalink
Comments (20)
Robert Shiller says economists and their models need to take bubbles
seriously (compare Dani Rodrik's "Blame Economists, not Economics"):
Economists need to study bubbles, reinvent models, by Robert Shiller,
Commentary, Project Syndicate: The widespread failure of economists to
forecast the financial crisis ... has much to do with faulty models. This lack
of sound models meant that economic policymakers and central bankers received no
warning of what was to come. ...
[T]he current financial crisis was driven by speculative bubbles in the housing
market, the stock market, energy and other commodities markets. ... You won’t
find the word “bubble,” however, in most economics treatises or textbooks.
Likewise, a search of working papers produced by central banks and economics
departments in recent years yields few instances of “bubbles” even being
mentioned. Indeed, the idea that bubbles exist has become so disreputable ...
that bringing them up in an economics seminar is like bringing up astrology to a
group of astronomers.
Continue reading ""Economists Need to Study Bubbles"" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 21, 2009 at 03:33 PM in Economics, Macroeconomics, Methodology |
Permalink
Comments (21)
Here's something I wrote for CBS Money Watch:
Who Should Oversee the Financial System?, by Mark Thoma
I expect many of you will disagree.
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 21, 2009 at 09:24 AM in Economics, Financial System, Regulation |
Permalink
Comments (30)
Lee Arnold says via email "this is interesting." It's an analysis of when and if economic growth should be maximized when technological progress involves risks as well as
benefits:
The Costs of Economic Growth, by Charles I. Jones, Stanford GSB and NBER, August
18, 2009: 1. Introduction In October 1962, the Cuban missile crisis
brought the world to the brink of a nuclear holocaust. President John F. Kennedy
put the chance of nuclear war at “somewhere between one out of three and even.”
The historian Arthur Schlesinger, Jr., at the time an adviser of the President,
later called this “the most dangerous moment in human history.”1 What if a
substantial fraction of the world’s population had been killed in a nuclear
holocaust in the 1960s? In some sense, the overall cost of the technological
innovations of the preceding 30 years would then seem to have outweighed the
benefits.
While nuclear devastation represents a vivid example of the potential costs of
technological change, it is by no means unique. The benefits from the internal
combustion engine must be weighed against the costs associated with pollution
and global warming. Biomedical advances have improved health substantially but
made possible weaponized anthrax and lab-enhanced viruses. The potential
benefits of nanotechnology stand beside the threat that a self-replicating
machine could someday spin out of control. Experimental physics has brought us
x-ray lithography techniques and superconductor technologies but also the remote
possibility of devastating accidents as we smash particles together at ever
higher energies. These and other technological dangers are detailed in a small
but growing literature on so-called “existential risks”; Posner (2004) is likely
the most familiar of these references, but see also Bostrom (2002), Joy (2000),
Overbye (2008), and Rees (2003).
Technologies need not pose risks to the existence of humanity in order to have
costs worth considering. New technologies come with risks as well as benefits. A
new pesticide may turn out to be harmful to children. New drugs may have
unforeseen side effects. Marie Curie’s discovery of the new element radium led
to many uses of the glow-in-the-dark material, including a medicinal additive to
drinks and baths for supposed health benefits, wristwatches with luminous dials,
and as makeup — at least until the dire health consequences of radioactivity
were better understood. Other examples of new products that were initially
thought to be safe or even healthy include thalidomide, lead paint, asbestos,
and cigarettes.
The benefits of economic growth are truly amazing and have made enormous
contributions to welfare. However, this does not mean there are not also costs.
How does this recognition affect the theory of economic growth?
This paper explores what might be called a “Russian roulette” theory of economic
growth. Suppose the overwhelming majority of new ideas are beneficial and lead
to growth in consumption. However, there is a tiny chance that a new idea will
be particularly dangerous and cause massive loss of life. Do discovery and
economic growth continue forever in such a framework, or should society
eventually decide that consumption is high enough and stop playing the game of
Russian roulette? The answer turns out to depend on preferences. For a large
class of conventional specifications, including log utility, safety eventually
trumps economic growth. The optimal rate of growth may be substantially lower
than what is feasible, in some cases falling all the way to zero.
Continue reading ""The Costs of Economic Growth"" »
Posted by Mark Thoma on Monday, September 21, 2009 at 09:21 AM in Economics, Technology |
Permalink
Comments (8)