Why Do We Use Core Inflation?: There is a lot of confusion over the Fed's
use of core inflation as part of its policy making process. One reason for
confusion is that we using a single measure to summarize three different
definitions of the term "core inflation" based upon how it is used.
First, core inflation is used to forecast future inflation. For example,
this recent paper uses a "bivariate integrated moving average ... model ...
that fits the data on inflation very well," and finds that the long-run trend
rate of inflation "is best gauged by focusing solely on prices excluding food
and energy prices." That is, this paper finds that predictions of future
inflation based upon core measures are more accurate than predictions based upon
total inflation.
Second, we also use the core inflation rate to measure the current trend
inflation rate. Because the inflation rate we observe contains both permanent
and transitory components, the precise long-run inflation rate that consumers
face going forward is not observed directly, it must be estimated. When food and
energy are removed to obtain a core measure, the idea is to strip away the
short-run movements thereby giving a better picture of the core or long-run
inflation rate faced by households. I should note, however that this is not the
only nor the best way to extract the trend and the Fed also looks at other
measures of the trend inflation rate that have better statistical properties.
Thus while the first use of core inflation was for forecasting future inflation
rates, this use of core inflation attempts to find today's trend inflation rate
[There is a way to combine the first and second uses into a single conceptual
framework that encompasses both, but it seemed more intuitive to keep them
separate. In both cases, the idea is to find the inflation rate that consumers
are likely to face in the future.]
Let me emphasize one thing. If the question is "what is today's inflation
rate," the total inflation rate is the best measure. It's intended to measure
the cost of living and there's no reason at all to strip anything out. It's only
when we ask different questions that different measures are used.
Third, and this is the function that is ignored most often in discussions of
core inflation, but to me it is the most important of the three. The
inflation target that best stabilizes the economy (i.e. best reduces the
variation in output and employment) is a version of core inflation.
In theoretical models used to study monetary policy, the procedure for
setting the policy rule is to find the monetary policy rule that maximizes
household welfare (by minimizing variation in variables such as output,
consumption, and employment). The rule will vary by model, but it usually
involves a measure of output and a measure of prices, and those measures can be
in levels, rates of change, or both depending upon the particular model being
examined.
In general, a Taylor rule type framework comes out of this process (
i.e. a rule that links the federal funds rate to measures of output and prices). However, in the
policy rule, the best measure of prices is usually something
that looks like a core measure of inflation. Essentially, when prices are
sticky, which is the most common assumption driving the interaction between
policy and movements in real variables in these models, it's best to target an
index that gives most of the weight to the stickiest prices (here's
an explanation as to why from a post that echoes the themes here).
That is, volatile prices such as food and energy are essentially tossed out of
the index used in the policy rule.
The indexes that come out of this type of theoretical exercise often includes both output and input
prices, and occasionally asset prices as well. That is, a core measure of
inflation composed of just output prices isn't the best thing for policymakers
to target, a more general core inflation rate combining both input and output
prices works better. ...
Finally, there is also a question of what we mean by inflation conceptually.
Does a change in relative prices, e.g. from a large increase in energy costs,
that raises the cost of living substantially count as inflation, or do we
require the changes to be common across all prices as would occur when the money
supply is increased? Which is better for measuring the cost of living? Which is
a better target for stabilizing the economy? The answers may not be the same.
For a nice discussion of this topic, see this speech given yesterday by Dennis
Lockhart, President of the Atlanta Fed:
Inflation Beyond the Headlines, by Dennis P. Lockhart, President, Federal
Reserve Bank of Atlanta: ...Let me begin by posing the simple question:
What do we mean by "inflation"? The answer to that simple question isn't as
simple as it may seem.
The popular treatment of inflation in our sound bite society risks
confusing inflation with relative price movements and the cost of living. By
cost of living, I'm referring to the costs you and I incur to maintain our
level of consumption of various goods and services including essential items
such as food, gasoline, and lodging.
Relative price movements occur continuously in an economy as individual
prices react to market forces affecting that good or service. Neither
relative price movements nor sustained high living costs constitute
inflation as economists commonly use the term....
And I think I'll end with this part of his remarks:
Attempts to measure the aggregate rate of price change—no matter how
sophisticated—remain imperfect. As a result, when it comes to measuring
inflation, judgment is needed to distinguish persistent price movements that
underlie overall inflation from the relative price adjustments. Separating
the inflation signal from noise involves much uncertainty—especially when
making decisions in real time. Discerning accurately the underlying trend is
difficult. It is essential for those of us who have responsibility for
responding to these trends to use a wide variety of core measures and
inflation projections to make the most informed judgment we can.